MINIBOSS BUSINESS SCHOOL Franchise

MINIBOSS BUSINESS SCHOOL Franchise
International Business Academy Consortium

Tuesday, 14 October 2025

Nobel Prize in Economics 2025: Joel Mokyr, Philippe Aghion and Peter Howitt named laureates


This image was created using AI as an independent illustration for this article. Any similarities or differences to actual figures are purely coincidental. Copyright: 100% NEWS Editorial Team.

Innovation as the Engine of Prosperity: Why the 2025 Economics Nobel Matters Now

By Prof. Andrii Azarov, International Business Academy Consortium (IBAC)

The Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences has awarded the 2025 Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel to Joel Mokyr, Philippe Aghion and Peter Howitt “for explaining innovation-driven economic growth”. The monetary award is SEK 11 million: half goes to Mokyr; Aghion and Howitt share the other half equally. The decision was announced in Stockholm on 13 October 2025.

Why these three

The laureates connect the deep mechanics of long-run prosperity to technological change and creative destruction—the competitive process through which new products, firms and ideas displace obsolete ones. Their contributions explain:

  • How sustained growth became possible after centuries of near-stagnation (Mokyr).
  • Which institutional settings amplify or suppress these forces—from open science and engineering competence to competition policy and social insurance.
  • How innovation drives productivity at the firm level yet aggregates to a stable growth path (Aghion–Howitt).

Joel Mokyr: the preconditions of sustained growth

Joel Mokyr (Northwestern University) demonstrated that long-run growth rests on a cumulative stock of useful knowledge and the mechanical competence to apply it. He distinguishes between propositional knowledge (understanding how nature works) and prescriptive knowledge (know-how in production). When institutions lower the cost of accessing and exchanging both—learned societies, journals, standards, apprenticeships—and when society tolerates the disruption of new methods, the feedback loop between science and practice accelerates. That is how the world moved from episodic bursts of progress to an era of continuous improvement.

Philippe Aghion & Peter Howitt: growth through creative destruction

Philippe Aghion (Collège de France/INSEAD/LSE) and Peter Howitt (Brown University) formalised a growth paradigm in which innovations replace incumbent technologies. In their framework, entrepreneurs invest in R&D to “escape competition”; successful innovators earn temporary rents; laggards exit or adapt; resources reallocate to higher-productivity uses. Crucially, the model reconciles micro-level turbulence (entry, exit, job reallocation) with macro-level stability (a sustained growth trend), and it illuminates why competition and innovation are linked in a nuanced, often inverted-U relationship: too little rivalry dulls effort; cut-throat rivalry kills returns to R&D.

Why it matters now

With rapid advances in AI, an expensive green transition, and renewed geopolitical fragmentation, the Committee’s choice underscores a simple truth: innovation mechanisms must be deliberately nurtured. Economies that weaken competition, restrict knowledge flows, or entrench incumbents risk a slide into low-productivity equilibria.

Three implications follow:

  1. Make markets contestable. Competition policy and open trade enlarge the payoff to invention and diffusion; protectionism shrinks it.
  2. Cushion the transition, don’t block it. Social insurance, reskilling and labour mobility are complements to innovation—not substitutes—because creative destruction is beneficial system-wide yet locally painful.
  3. Back knowledge infrastructure. Stable funding of basic research, interoperable standards, and open scientific exchange reduce the cost of recombining ideas.

Quick bios

  • Joel Mokyr (b. 1946, Leiden): economic historian whose work shows how the accumulation and diffusion of useful knowledge—paired with engineering practice and tolerant institutions—ignite sustained growth; Professor at Northwestern University.
  • Peter Howitt (b. 1946, Canada): co-author of the Aghion–Howitt model; Professor Emeritus, Brown University; pioneer of the micro-to-macro link in innovation-led growth.
  • Philippe Aghion (b. 1956, Paris): leading scholar of growth, competition and industrial policy; architect of modern Schumpeterian growth theory; Collège de France / INSEAD / LSE.

Five ideas at the core of the prize

  1. Innovation drives growth. Capital deepening explains little without a continual flow of new ideas.
  2. Scale magnifies incentives. Larger, open markets increase the expected returns to R&D; fragmentation erodes them.
  3. Institutions are decisive. Law, education, research infrastructure and a culture that values “useful knowledge” determine whether societies adopt new technology.
  4. Creative destruction is productive—and disruptive. Policy should mitigate private losses (through safety nets and mobility) without muting competition.
  5. Policy is calibration, not dirigisme. Enforce contestable markets; fund foundational science; use targeted, time-bounded incentives (e.g., for green and digital technologies).

What makes the Economics Prize distinctive

Strictly speaking, this award is not among Alfred Nobel’s original prizes. It was established by Sveriges Riksbank in 1968 for the bank’s 300th anniversary and is conferred under the same rules and ceremonies. The first laureates were Ragnar Frisch and Jan Tinbergen in 1969.

Implications for policy and business

For governments

  • Competition & openness: Maintain contestability in product, capital and data markets; avoid creeping protectionism.
  • Smart, not sprawling subsidies: Prioritise enabling platforms (testing facilities, compute for AI research, grid flexibility) over firm-specific bailouts.
  • R&D architecture: Fund basic research; support translational institutes that bridge labs and factories; simplify IP where diffusion is essential.
  • Skills & mobility: Scale apprenticeships and mid-career reskilling in engineering-rich domains; remove barriers to worker and firm entry.

For corporates

  • Invest in discovery & deployment. Balance incremental improvements with a portfolio of bets on general-purpose technologies.
  • Build with openness. University partnerships, shared testbeds and interoperable standards reduce the cost and time to scale.
  • Design for rivalry. Organise internal “neck-and-neck” competition on measurable productivity outcomes, not vanity metrics.

For society

  • Fair transitions. Creative destruction creates aggregate gains but local shocks; robust safety nets and portable benefits are complements to innovation.
  • Trust in science. Predictable rules for research integrity and data governance sustain the social licence for technological change.

At a glance

  • Prize fund: SEK 11 million (Mokyr 1/2; Aghion 1/4; Howitt 1/4) - about 1 million euros. 
  • Award ceremony: 10 December, anniversary of Alfred Nobel’s death.
  • Announcement: 13 October 2025, Stockholm. 

Official facts about the laureates

Joel Mokyr — The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2025
Born: 26 July 1946, Leiden, the Netherlands
Affiliation at the time of the award: Northwestern University (Evanston, IL, USA); Eitan Berglas School of Economics, Tel Aviv University (Israel)
Prize motivation: “for having identified the prerequisites for sustained growth through technological progress”
Prize share: 1/2

Philippe Aghion — The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2025
Born: 17 August 1956, Paris, France
Affiliation at the time of the award: Collège de France (Paris), INSEAD (Paris), London School of Economics and Political Science (London)
Prize motivation: “for the theory of sustained growth through creative destruction”
Prize share: 1/4

Peter Howitt — The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2025
Born: 31 May 1946, Canada
Affiliation at the time of the award: Brown University (Providence, Rhode Island, USA)
Prize motivation: “for the theory of sustained growth through creative destruction”
Prize share: 1/4

More at the official website: https://www.nobelprize.org/prizes/economic-sciences/

___________________________________________

Editor’s note (100% NEWS): we will continue to track reactions across academia and markets, and how the laureates’ ideas shape economic policy in the EU and the US.

Prepared for the 100% NEWS Information Agency.

 


Advanced information
Scientific background

Sustained economic growth through technological progress 



1 Introduction 

On a daily basis, we are reminded of how fast technology progresses and how it changes the world aroundus. New discoveries and new innovations affect our lives directly and they also fundamentally affect the economy. Technological change is of course not a new phenomenon. Progress and innovations have occurred since ancient times. What is relatively recent, however, viewed against the entire history of humankind, is the type of innovation-driven economic growth enjoyed by the advanced countries of the world during the last two centuries, and how such high growth rates are sustained.

Figure 1 shows the striking lack of persistent economic growth for a longer pre-industrial period, despite some major scientific and technical breakthroughs. The picture shows GDP per capita in England, where historical national accounts have been constructed going back to the 13th century (Broadberry et al., 2015), and is broadly representative of human history across the world up until 1700.

Figure 1: GDP per capita in England 1300–1680, paired with selected innovations and breakthroughs 

GDP per capita in Geary-Khamis 1990 dollars. The y-axis is logarithmic. Data sources: Broadberry et al. (2015). 


In contrast to Figure 1, Figure 2 shows economic growth since 1800 of two countries at the world’s
technological frontier: the United Kingdom (panel (a) on the left) and the United States (panel (b) on
the right). Although these countries have experienced significant turbulence over this time period, and swings or dips are visible in this graph, the most striking aspect of the figure is the long period of remarkably sustained economic growth. 

How could economic growth become a sustained phenomenon? And what keeps us on the current path? These are first-order questions for the economies of the world. This year’s laureates have addressed these questions in highly complementary research efforts from different perspectives and with different methods.

 

GDP per capita in USD in 2011 prices. The y-axes are logarithmic, i.e., a straight line can be interpreted as a constant growth rate. Data source: Maddison Project Database 2023 with underlying sources for the United Kingdom: Broadberry et al. (2015) and for the U.S.: Sutch (2006) and de la Escosura (2009).

Joel Mokyr, an economic historian, studied how growth became sustained as a result of a set of key prerequisites that were not jointly present prior to the Industrial Revolution, but have been since then. Of central importance is how science interacts with technology, i.e., economic production in practice, and that society welcomes technological change. One of his main study objects, quite naturally, was the Industrial Revolution, since it defined the transition between the two regimes in Figures 1 and 2.

Philippe Aghion and Peter Howitt instead were inspired by the sustained economic growth of modern times and how disruptive this process is underneath the aggregate. They developed a theory of growth through “creative destruction”, describing the process of innovation and “business stealing” and how the long-run growth rate of an economy is determined as a result. The theory contains fundamental building blocks of how new technology surpasses old, where some firms win at the expense of other firms, in an economy characterized by constant churning.

The starting point of this year’s laureates’ contributions is the view that innovation and technological change are the key drivers of sustained economic growth. This point was forcefully made by Robert Solow (1986 economics laureate), whose growth accounting method (Solow, 1957) suggests that growth is not primarily driven by physical or human capital accumulation. The question of what drives technological change itself was not formally addressed until the early 1990s, when Paul Romer (2017 economics laureate) developed theories around knowledge accumulation and emphasized key attributes like the non-rival nature of ideas. These studies, however, did not address how economic growth could emerge in the first place as a sustained phenomenon, nor did they examine or empirically evaluate the exact mechanisms propelling growth further and further. Even taking for granted that innovations and technological change are the key driver of economic growth, innovations predate the period of sustained economic growth by millennia. This year’s laureates both explain how innovations feed into sustained economic growth, and how a regime emerged in which new products and processes are continuously introduced in the marketplace despite the conflicting interests they create. A similar pattern of sustained economic growth can be seen since 1800 in other advanced economies (see Appendix Figure A1).

Mokyr’s novel answer centers around how innovation accelerates when scientific breakthroughs and practical knowledge reinforce each other. In particular, his studies link a number of key observations. First, philosophical and theoretical advancements had been recorded dating back thousands of years. Second, the development of applied technology—new tools, products, and methods of production that are central ingredients into how production occurs—had been pushed forward for ages. Third, each of these phenomena had always occurred in relatively short bursts and, throughout time, ground to a halt. Taken together, this produced a pattern of economic growth that in most of human history resembled long periods of stagnation or very slow growth, punctuated by sudden outbursts of short-lived economic dynamism. All of this changed with the Industrial Revolution, when the world saw sustained growth rates for the first time in history. In a string of focused, but crucially related, contributions, Mokyr (1990a, 2002, 2009) arrived at a synthesis that puts the interplay between science and applied technology at the heart of the articulation. The Enlightenment, in particular, was a major burst to science, but it did not mechanically generate applications that led to economic growth; for that, the practitioners were key. At the same time, Mokyr also documents how new innovations challenged old ways and met resistance from established interest groups wanting to thwart technological change. Therefore, intellectual tolerance for new ways of thinking and openness to ideas was crucial for removing major roadblocks to technological progress. Practitioners, ready to engage with science, along with a societal climate embracing change, were, according to Mokyr, key reasons why the Industrial Revolution started in Britain. Mokyr’s narrative is constructed from a wide variety of historical sources from all of human history and both qualitative and quantitative work. The narrative has also been successfully tested with econometric studies by Mokyr himself as well as others.

Rather than looking into the distant past, Aghion and Howitt were motivated by observing modern-day sustained, innovation-led growth in advanced economies. Aghion and Howitt set out to understand, via theoretical formalization, how entrepreneurs innovate: how they create new ideas and introduce better products and processes in the marketplace, and how their actions are shaped by the regulatory environment. In other words, being guided by how innovations come about in practice in today’s society, Aghion and Howitt put entrepreneurs and their decisions at center stage and analyzed the process of creative destruction. The idea is that an innovation leads to business stealing: the innovation is carried out in one firm, or by one individual, but partially destroys the rents of others. They constructed a mathematical framework designed to study how individual decisions and conflicting interests at the microeconomic firm level can lead to steady output growth at the aggregate level. The theory is empirically persuasive—it matches a range of relevant microeconomic and macroeconomic facts—and generated an avalanche of follow-up studies linking competition and firm dynamics to growth. The basic model proposed by Aghion and Howitt (1992), and the literature that followed, described innovations not as complementary to pre-existing activities, as in Romer’s work, but as another polar case whereby new goods are perfect substitutes with old ones, and in fact simply better than existing goods. This perspective introduces the elements of creative destruction and conflicting interests. Aghion and Howitt’s approach fundamentally relies on the heterogeneity and competing relations among firms, allowing us to test the theories of aggregate growth, and quantify their mechanisms, by looking at microeconomic, firm-level data. It also allows us to evaluate counter-factual policy experiments explicitly, e.g., changes in patent protection, competition policies or R&D subsidies. Their model, with its countless extensions, has become the workhorse model for analyzing positive and normative questions regarding innovation-led growth.

Mokyr’s broad perspective and Aghion and Howitt’s analytical precision provide us with tools that are crucial in today’s world. Sustained technological development has allowed human conditions to steadily improve for more than 200 years. Two centuries, however, is just a small fraction of human history and the continuation of this trend is not to be taken for granted. Impediments to the open exchange of ideas and fading support for science could pose future threats to economic growth. Another challenge is how to regulate dominant tech or pharmaceutical companies without harming the technological progress they create. At the same time, there are also opportunities: new technologies such as artificial intelligence could grease the positive feedback loop between science and applied technology and may—in the right regulatory and societal environment—even lead to faster progress. Together, the contributions of this year’s laureates have provided us with tools and offer important insights into how to address threats to progress and make the best out of future opportunities.

The document proceeds as follows: the next section, Section 2, describes the findings by Mokyr in more detail. Section 3 then continues with a discussion of the contribution by Aghion and Howitt. Section 4 concludes.

Joel Mokyr, an economic historian, studied how growth became sustained as a result of a set of key prerequisites that were not jointly present prior to the Industrial Revolution, but have been since then. Of central importance is how science interacts with technology, i.e., economic production in practice, and that society welcomes technological change. One of his main study objects, quite naturally, was the Industrial Revolution, since it defined the transition between the two regimes in Figures 1 and 2.

Philippe Aghion and Peter Howitt instead were inspired by the sustained economic growth of modern times and how disruptive this process is underneath the aggregate. They developed a theory of growth through “creative destruction”, describing the process of innovation and “business stealing” and how the long-run growth rate of an economy is determined as a result. The theory contains fundamental building blocks of how new technology surpasses old, where some firms win at the expense of other firms, in an economy characterized by constant churning.

The starting point of this year’s laureates’ contributions is the view that innovation and technological change are the key drivers of sustained economic growth. This point was forcefully made by Robert Solow (1986 economics laureate), whose growth accounting method (Solow, 1957) suggests that growth is not primarily driven by physical or human capital accumulation. The question of what drives technological change itself was not formally addressed until the early 1990s, when Paul Romer (2017 economics laureate) developed theories around knowledge accumulation and emphasized key attributes like the non-rival nature of ideas. These studies, however, did not address how economic growth could emerge in the first place as a sustained phenomenon, nor did they examine or empirically evaluate the exact mechanisms propelling growth further and further. Even taking for granted that innovations and technological change are the key driver of economic growth, innovations predate the period of sustained economic growth by millennia. This year’s laureates both explain how innovations feed into sustained economic growth, and how a regime emerged in which new products and processes are continuously introduced in the marketplace despite the conflicting interests they create.

Mokyr’s novel answer centers around how innovation accelerates when scientific breakthroughs and practical knowledge reinforce each other. In particular, his studies link a number of key observations. First, philosophical and theoretical advancements had been recorded dating back thousands of years. Second, the development of applied technology—new tools, products, and methods of production that are central ingredients into how production occurs—had been pushed forward for ages. Third, each of these phenomena had always occurred in relatively short bursts and, throughout time, ground to a halt. Taken together, this produced a pattern of economic growth that in most of human history resembled long periods of stagnation or very slow growth, punctuated by sudden outbursts of short-lived economic dynamism. All of this changed with the Industrial Revolution, when the world saw sustained growth rates for the first time in history. In a string of focused, but crucially related, contributions, Mokyr (1990a, 2002, 2009) arrived at a synthesis that puts the interplay between science and applied technology at the heart of the articulation. The Enlightenment, in particular, was a major burst to science, but it did not mechanically generate applications that led to economic growth; for that, the practitioners were key. At the same time, Mokyr also documents how new innovations challenged old ways and met resistance from established interest groups wanting to thwart technological change. Therefore, intellectual tolerance for new ways of thinking and openness to ideas was crucial for removing major roadblocks to technological progress. Practitioners, ready to engage with science, along with a societal climate embracing change, were, according to Mokyr, key reasons why the Industrial Revolution started in Britain. Mokyr’s narrative is constructed from a wide variety of historical sources from all of human history and both qualitative and quantitative work. The narrative has also been successfully tested with econometric studies by Mokyr himself as well as others.

Rather than looking into the distant past, Aghion and Howitt were motivated by observing modern-day sustained, innovation-led growth in advanced economies. Aghion and Howitt set out to understand, via theoretical formalization, how entrepreneurs innovate: how they create new ideas and introduce better products and processes in the marketplace, and how their actions are shaped by the regulatory environment. In other words, being guided by how innovations come about in practice in today’s society, Aghion and Howitt put entrepreneurs and their decisions at center stage and analyzed the process of creative destruction. The idea is that an innovation leads to business stealing: the innovation is carried out in one firm, or by one individual, but partially destroys the rents of others. They constructed a mathematical framework designed to study how individual decisions and conflicting interests at the microeconomic firm level can lead to steady output growth at the aggregate level. The theory is empirically persuasive—it matches a range of relevant microeconomic and macroeconomic facts—and generated an avalanche of follow-up studies linking competition and firm dynamics to growth. The basic model proposed by Aghion and Howitt (1992), and the literature that followed, described innovations not as complementary to pre-existing activities, as in Romer’s work, but as another polar case whereby new goods are perfect substitutes with old ones, and in fact simply better than existing goods. This perspective introduces the elements of creative destruction and conflicting interests. Aghion and Howitt’s approach fundamentally relies on the heterogeneity and competing relations among firms, allowing us to test the theories of aggregate growth, and quantify their mechanisms, by looking at microeconomic, firm-level data. It also allows us to evaluate counter-factual policy experiments explicitly, e.g., changes in patent protection, competition policies or R&D subsidies. Their model, with its countless extensions, has become the workhorse model for analyzing positive and normative questions regarding innovation-led growth.

Mokyr’s broad perspective and Aghion and Howitt’s analytical precision provide us with tools that are crucial in today’s world. Sustained technological development has allowed human conditions to steadily improve for more than 200 years. Two centuries, however, is just a small fraction of human history and the continuation of this trend is not to be taken for granted. Impediments to the open exchange of ideas and fading support for science could pose future threats to economic growth. Another challenge is how to regulate dominant tech or pharmaceutical companies without harming the technological progress they create. At the same time, there are also opportunities: new technologies such as artificial intelligence could grease the positive feedback loop between science and applied technology and may—in the right regulatory and societal environment—even lead to faster progress. Together, the contributions of this year’s laureates have provided us with tools and offer important insights into how to address threats to progress and make the best out of future opportunities.

The document proceeds as follows: the next section, Section 2, describes the findings by Mokyr in more detail. Section 3 then continues with a discussion of the contribution by Aghion and Howitt. Section 4 concludes.

2 The takeoff into a long era of growth

Part of this year’s Prize in Economic Sciences is awarded to Mokyr for having provided an explanation for how industrial takeoffs can transform into sustained and self-propelling economic growth. By contrasting the sporadic searches and haphazardness that characterized the invention process throughout most of human history with the scientific research program that took hold of Europe after the Enlightenment, Mokyr (1990a, 2002, 2009) explains why economic growth did not peter out after the first decades of the Industrial Revolution. The Enlightenment, a pan-European movement, paved the way for a fruitful dialogue between theoretical and practical knowledge and created the virtuous cycles of knowledge accumulation that allowed Europe (or more specifically, Britain) to embark on an innovation process powerful enough to generate sustained growth for the first time in history. It was not until the British Industrial Revolution that the modern process of creative destruction emerged. This was when cumulative knowledge had become powerful enough to create new disruptive technologies, which were allowed to diffuse widely in society, despite destroying existing rents. As the “mother of all creative destruction” (Mokyr, 2020, p. 714), the Industrial Revolution provides a fundamental example of the forces needed to maintain a takeoff into sustained growth: a joint evolution of science and technology, mechanical competence and a wider acceptance of the forces of creative destruction.

Below, we begin by motivating the ideas about takeoff and sustained economic growth with historical data. The document then remarks on the point of departure in the literature when Mokyr’s work emerged. Thereafter, the contribution and the empirical evidence and empirical follow-up studies are described, and finally the impact of Mokyr’s work is discussed.

2.1 Motivating evidence

By studying technological creativity in various historical societies, Mokyr (1990a) noted that some societies were highly creative, while others were much less so, without this having much relationship to the process of economic growth. Yet history did experience periods of short-lived economic expansion. Figure 3 provides examples with recently constructed GDP per capita series from six European pre-industrial economies, summarized and discussed by Fouquet and Broadberry (2015). The figure shows that Italy (during the Renaissance of the 15th and 16th centuries), Sweden (during its Great Power Era in the 17th century), and Holland (during the Dutch Golden Age, commonly set between 1588 and 1672) all experienced pre-industrial growth periods that eventually fizzled out, failing to produce a takeoff.

Instead, the takeoff took place in Britain with the Industrial Revolution (dates commonly set between 1760 and 1830 by, e.g., Ashton (1948)). As shown in Figure 3, growth rates started to increase already in the late 17th century. However, what set Britain apart from the rest of the sample experiencing periods of positive growth was that these rates became sustained, building up to the first takeoff into modern economic growth.

Figure 4 places the takeoff in longer historical context. The figure clearly shows that any kind of pre-industrial growth displayed in Figure 3 is massively overshadowed by the type of growth that took off with the Industrial Revolution. After Britain, economic takeoffs into sustained growth have occurred in several countries. Today, growth rates averaging some 1–2% annually have become the norm in most industrial countries, as outlined in Appendix Figure A1. This new pattern of sustained economic growth has subsequently raised average GDP per capita in the world (see Figure 4) very significantly, which in practice means that the last centuries of human history have, for the first time, implied continuous, significant improvements in living standards. Given the contrast between “before” and “after,” a key question is what allowed the transition to occur. A related question is why did the transition not occur earlier, or later? And is there a risk of a reversal back to a stagnant era? It is into this complex set of questions that Mokyr’s research has given us crucial insights.

2.2 Points of departure

For most of the 20th century, historians and economic historians searched for clues by investigating a number of specificities of the British Industrial Revolution. A key hypothesis was that this important

Figure notes. GDP per capita in Geary-Khamis 1990 dollars. All series in three-year average, except Spain (in 11-year average). The figure reproduces data published in Fouquet and Broadberry (2015). Data sources: England/Great Britain: Broadberry et al. (2015) (England from 1300 until 1700, Great Britain afterwards); Italy: Malanima (2011) (specifically central and northern Italian states from 1310); Holland: Van Zanden and Van Leeuwen (2012); Sweden: Sch¨on and Krantz (2012); Spain: Alvarez-Nogal and De La Escosura (2013); Portugal: Palma and Reis (2019).
 

economic event could be explained by economic factors, such as relative prices, endowments, demand factors, investment, exports, savings, property rights, changes in labor supply, and fiscal and monetary institutions, that differed between Britain and other countries (2). Among the many explanations, the role of science in the Industrial Revolution remained contentious. It was commonly argued that “science had little guidance to offer” (e.g., Hall (1974, p. 151)) and that only very few early inventions could be seen as directly traceable to new discoveries by scientists such as Galileo, Descartes, or Newton (3). The standard view instead resorted to explaining the Industrial Revolution with factors already embedded in the European societies before the takeoff, with many scholars championing a vision of a gradually rising West, (e.g., North and Thomas (1973); Landes (1969, 1998)). For a long time, this view was also supported by the pioneering data collection in Maddison (2001), which gave tentative support to the idea that Western Europe overtook China around the 16th century (4).

 

Figure notes. GDP per capita in USD in 2011 prices. Data sources: Maddison database (MPD 2023), with underlying sources for China: Broadberry et al. (2018); Xu et al. (2017); United States: McCusker (2006); Sutch (2006); de la Escosura (2009); United Kingdom: Broadberry et al. (2015)

Simultaneously, a parallel literature in economic history focused on measurement of macroeconomic variables and producing long-time series (e.g., Deane and Cole (1962)). With the compilation and creation of new time series data, researchers noted the surprisingly low growth rates (by modern standards) during the allegedly revolutionary late 18th and early 19th century in Britain. A revisionist view of the Industrial Revolution emerged, viewing it as a gradual acceleration onto a steady but unspectacular growth path with rapid productivity advances confined to relatively few sectors (Harley, 1982; Crafts, 1985; Crafts and Harley, 1992) (5). The new quantitative evidence led some to argue that the Industrial Revolution had been “dethroned” almost entirely, leaving behind only a description of gradual structural change from agrarian to non-agrarian sectors (Berg and Hudson, 1992). Thus, there was barely anything left to explain. 

2.3 Mokyr’s contribution

Mokyr (1990a, 2002) adopted a different perspective. He reformulated the debate by centering it on the impact of technological change on growth. Tracing the inventions and innovations that have transformed society since ancient China, Greece and Rome, and then evaluating the role of each technology, he concluded that technology had historically failed to produce growth because little was known about how and why the techniques worked. It was “a world of engineering without mechanics, iron-making without 

metallurgy, farming without soil science, mining without geology, water-power without hydraulics, dye-making without organic chemistry, and medical practice without microbiology and immunology” (Mokyr, 2005b, p. 1119).

To explain why technologies historically had failed to produce sustained growth, Mokyr (1990a,b) distinguished between major breakthroughs (“macro inventions”) and incremental improvements (“micro inventions”). Macro inventions are radical technological discontinuities determined by some shift in people’s knowledge or understanding or in a new combination of previously disparate ideas with potentially large effect on the marginal product of further improvements. Micro inventions, on the other hand, are incremental improvements to existing technologies explained by changes in economic supply and demand (6). That is, micro inventions are closer to everyday economic life and provide a key link between technology and the economy.

While macro inventions were not new to history—e.g., think of the windmill, the printing press, or the weight-driven mechanical clock—they emerged sporadically and failed to generate a stream of cumulative micro inventions supplementing the new techniques. Likewise, the drift of cumulative micro inventions resulted in many incremental improvements that soon ran into diminishing returns in the absence of new, more abstract ideas that widened the horizon. When no one knew why things worked, even radical technological shifts failed to generate the applications that made them useful in production processes. In such a world, economic resources were not allocated towards improving technologies, as potential investors were just as likely to waste valuable resources on fruitless inventions that would never work, such as perpetual motion machines or artificially created gold (Mokyr, 2002, p. 31–32).

The lack of a positive feedback loop between macro and micro inventions meant that even radical technological shifts always failed to result in anything but another technological plateau. While periods with rapid technological change could sometimes almost resemble the very early stages of the Industrial Revolution, or a takeoff, new innovations never accumulated enough feedback to produce sustained growth, i.e., a burst of activity that lasted for more than a few decades. Thus, technological progress during the period before the Industrial Revolution was very different from what took place after. With this insight, Mokyr identified a number of key prerequisites for sustaining economic growth.

A joint evolution of science and technology. A first key prerequisite for sustained growth, according to Mokyr, is the joint evolution of science and technology. The main event that allowed the transition to begin was the Enlightenment. However, what ultimately drove the takeoff into sustained economic growth was an expansion of “useful knowledge” (a term first introduced by Kuznets (1965)), powerful enough to break out of the long-run stasis.

In The Gifts of Athena, Mokyr (2002) developed the theory of the knowledge economy as a driver of sustained growth, able to generate positive feedback loops between macro and micro inventions. To explain how the acquisition of knowledge transformed itself such that it could sustain the Industrial Revolution beyond its first decades, Mokyr (2002) argued that useful knowledge rests on two types of knowledge. The first relates to knowledge about natural phenomena and regularities of the physical world, and is referred to as “propositional knowledge”. The second dictates how things work in practice and is referred to as “prescriptive knowledge”. Propositional knowledge serves as the support for the techniques carried out when economic production takes place. Although broadly similar to the standard distinction between “science” and “applied technology”, or “theory” and “empirical knowledge”, the concepts differ. Propositional knowledge is not science in a modern sense, since it could contain theories and observations of importance to the way techniques were historically carried out, and yet today be regarded as incorrect. It was not until propositional knowledge started to contain more scientifically tested and tried components that the knowledge base came closer to the type of formal and generalized propositional knowledge that we today know as science (7). While propositional knowledge feeds into prescriptive knowledge, prescriptive knowledge can generate feedback into propositional knowledge. The simplest feedback occurs when a technique is discovered by trial and error, and the fact that it works is registered as a known regularity of the world. Further testing and tweaking may add new and unexplained phenomena that further stimulate propositional knowledge. Similarly, changes in the execution of techniques may open up for new development of instruments and tools that further the feedback loop. The virtuous cycle is self-sustaining in the sense that the two types of knowledge are complementary and increase the marginal product of the other.

The Enlightenment revolutionized the way useful knowledge accumulated. To connect the scientific revolution of the 16th and 17th centuries to events taking place in the economy around a century later, Mokyr coined the term the “Industrial Enlightenment” (Mokyr, 2002, p. 35). This was a set of social changes that transformed the nature and size of propositional and prescriptive knowledge and their relationship. In Mokyr’s conception of the Industrial Enlightenment these social changes came about to: (i) reduce access costs to prescriptive knowledge by surveying artisanal practises to determine which techniques were superior, (ii) understand why techniques worked by generalizing them and trying to connect them with the formal propositional knowledge of the time, and (iii) facilitate the interaction between those that controlled the propositional knowledge and those that implemented the techniques contained in prescriptive knowledge.

The Industrial Enlightenment created new standards of open science, scientific methods and a common vocabulary making useful knowledge more diffused and accessible. By facilitating interaction, generalized propositional knowledge spread beyond the “more arcane realms of mathematics and experimental philosophy to the more mundane worlds of the artisan, the mechanic and the farmer” (Mokyr, 2002, p. 36). Gradually, the connection between propositional and prescriptive knowledge became tighter. By 1800, useful knowledge started to have a real impact on the economy, sustaining technological change and growth. The feedback from technological success further inspired confidence in the propositional knowledge underlying the techniques and advanced knowledge accumulation. Had it not been for the enlarged scientific knowledge base, technological progress would have slowed down, as in all previous historical instances of technical change. Instead, growth became sustained. Around 1870, science-based knowledge influenced virtually all branches of industrial production (Mokyr (2005b)).

Mechanical competence. New ideas need people that put them into economic use. Mechanical competence refers to the ability of agents to carry out the instructions derived from prescriptive knowledge. But the knowledge needed to execute a new technology is not the same as the knowledge needed to invent it. Technologically creative societies are those where highly educated people who think for themselves mingle with those who are skilled and produce goods and services for consumption. Crucial to economic growth were thus the skilled practitioners (sometimes referred to by Mokyr as “tinkerers,” “tweakers” or “implementers”) who possessed sufficient technical know-how to access new knowledge to read the blueprints, scale up the models, and install the equipment that put science into economic use, or in other words, people able to move easily between the world of abstraction and the practicalities of the lever, the cylinder and the spindle. The skills that mattered here were not just the average skills of the population (i.e., average literacy or schooling rates) but rather the skills and capabilities among the upper tail of those possessing human capital. Capable tinkerers ensured that new technologies kept being tweaked, tested, and improved, and that useful knowledge was put into economic applications.

A society open to change. The Enlightenment not only helped enlarge the scope of propositional knowledge and its connections to practical use, but it also governed the societal changes needed to release the disruptive forces of creative destruction into society. Pioneering a literature on the political economy of technological change, Mokyr (1990a, 1992) explained the frailty of the process of creative destruction. Mokyr documented that resistance to technology, a phenomenon largely ignored by historians, had been pervasive in history and often came from vested interests. These vested interests involved those whose assets (i.e., formal skills, tacit knowledge, reputation, specialized equipment, ownership of certain natural resources, or barriers to entry that secured monopoly positions, etc.) were somehow threatened by the new inventions. Vested interests could also be identified among those intellectuals who were opposed to new technology on principle (the latter being the main concern of Schumpeter (1942)). With the Enlightenment, however, a cultural shift in human beliefs and attitudes towards nature took place (8). A new willingness to harness nature to human needs helped overcome the barriers to technological change by creating a “culture of growth” that formed the basis for social and institutional change (9). Specifically, the Enlightenment paved the way for a new institutions that were flexible enough to encourage competition between interest groups and allow the winners to compensate the losers, for example by functioning parliaments where representatives from different interest groups could meet and negotiate their claims (10). With these societal changes in place, the forces of creative destruction could be released into society for the first time.

2.4 Tests and evidence

Mokyr bolstered his theoretical proposition by providing three types of empirical evidence: macro-level comparisons, an analytical narrative through historical case studies, and quantitative evidence. Below, we illustrate each of these in turn.

2.4.1 Macro-level comparisons

With large macro-comparisons from different historical periods and parts of the globe, Mokyr demonstrates that history has seen several periods of technological change that failed to translate into sustained economic growth. In every instance, one or several aspects of the key ingredients producing sustained growth—a joint evolution of science and technology, mechanical competence, and social acceptance of creative destruction—were lacking.

For example, the civilizations of ancient Greece and Rome were distinguished by advances in philosophy, geometry, architecture, and political science. Yet, these advancements failed to translate into practical products and techniques that could have been used for the betterment of human needs. As a result, technological progress in sectors impacting material living standards, such as agriculture, textiles, and the use of power and materials, were modest (Mokyr, 1990a, p. 20–29). Similarly, the Renaissance brought back the classical ideals and helped advance them in large numbers of new technical “how-to” books and manuals that diffused across society. Still, the distance between propositional and prescriptive knowledge remained large and the lack of local skilled labor and mechanics made it difficult to put theoretical ideas into practical use. New visions therefore often ended up being unrealized, just like Leonardo da Vinci’s thousands of sketches for machinery that were mostly left unrealized in his lifetime (Mokyr, 1990a, p. 72–73).

In contrast, the relatively backward society in medieval Europe (500–1500 AD)—often referred to as the “dark Middle Ages”—saw several practical innovations that transformed productive capacity. The three-field crop rotation system, the heavy plow, windmills, and bigger and better water wheels all served to increase agricultural production and energy utilization, resulting in urbanization and population growth. The problem was a general lack of understanding of why the things worked, resulting in an invention process that was too sporadic and scattered to generate a powerful takeoff into sustained growth.

The most central macro-level comparison in Mokyr’s work is that with China. Until the 14th century, China had a lead in technological development over Europe. Major Chinese innovations in plowing, blast furnaces, textiles, time measurement, maritime technology, paper production, and the production of porcelain, lacquers, explosives and pharmaceuticals eventually found their way to Europe, either as imports or by reinvention (Mokyr, 1990a, p. 209–219). Yet, China failed to experience an Industrial Revolution (11). Instead, innovation gradually slowed down. In some sectors, such as clockmaking and shipbuilding, even technological retrogression took place (Mokyr, 1990a, p. 220). China failed to develop a system of formal logic (Mokyr, 1990a, p. 229), and was not able to make the shift from the experience-based process of invention to more science-based methods (Lin, 1995). As the technological process was government-controlled and manipulated/managed by the Chinese court, China was kept on a technologically stagnant path due to lack of open science and competition. The best illustration of the reversal of technological creativity is the complete halt of geographical exploration after 1430 by a decision from the Chinese imperial court (12).

2.4.2 Analytical narrative

In part, Mokyr built his new perspective on innovation-driven growth on a large number of case studies, where his focus on why the Industrial Revolution was first seen in Britain is a prime example. His studies of vested interests also rest on numerous narratives. We now briefly discuss each of these.

Britain’s early advantage. While the Enlightenment movement was common to Western Europe, it was Britain that first created synergies that accelerated sustained technological innovation and growth. Drawing on a variety of sources, Mokyr (1990a, 2002) arrived at a synthesis consistent with both the timing and place of the Industrial Revolution, summarized and developed at length in Mokyr (2009) (13).

The argument was based on inductive reasoning obtained from of a multitude of different primary sources, such as biographies, letters, philosophers’ writing, technical manuals, government reports, and secondary sources (historiographies). Importantly, Mokyr (2009) stressed that the Industrial Revolution must be understood as a broader shift, involving the entire society (14). Outside the common tales of cotton textiles, wrought iron and steam power, technical improvements were seen across activities as varied as watchmaking, shipping, glassmaking, brewing, road transport, paper making, candlemaking, gas lighting, water power, and making ceramics and machine tools. Additionally, important breakthroughs encompassed discoveries as diverse as Newcomen’s atmospheric engine, the process of making soda, chlorine bleaching, the calculation of the trajectory of a projectile, the determination of longitude at sea, and smallpox inoculation and vaccination. Yet, it was not the early takeoff that produced the most crucial change, but rather the events in the early decades of the 19th century. This was when the feedback loops between propositional and prescriptive knowledge had become powerful enough to put the economy onto a new path, with innovation and growth rates that could be sustained over the long run (15).

It was thus the Enlightenment that brought the type of advances in propositional knowledge that proved crucial for accelerating the rate of technological progress. However, as France is often described as the epicenter of this intellectual movement, it is clear that the Enlightenment alone did not generate the advantage Britain had to take off. A key aspect of the argument by Mokyr (2009) is therefore that Britain had a comparative advantage in generating micro inventions from useful knowledge. That is, Britain possessed a comparably large and well-trained supply of skilled artisans and engineers (16). National celebrities such as James Watt, who improved the Newcomen steam engine, and Richard Arkwright, who invented the water frame and the modern cotton mill, stand out here. There were, however, many more: The Darbys of Coalbrookdale supplied the cylinders of the Newcomen engines; Arthur Woolf, the engineer and inventor of the compound steam engine; Bryan Donkin, who famously improved mechanized papermaking; or Joseph Bramah and Henry Maudslay, often regarded as the fathers of the British machine tool industry (Mokyr, 2009, p. 108–109). Below these famous industrialists were a layer of mechanics, clockmakers, toymakers, wood makers, glass cutters and metal workers, who understood the interdependence of mechanical parts and could experiment with novel usage of materials and techniques. With skills such as the ability to understand notation and spatial graphic representation and a basic sense of “what worked”, these mechanics possessed a major competence to carry out and adapt the instructions in the blueprints that allowed for a stream of micro inventions that perfected the novel techniques. Without this pool of mechanics, inventors like Arkwright and Watt would not have been able to turn their ideas into usable products.

Finally, Britain had several features that gave it a considerable, albeit temporary, advantage. Most importantly, Britain’s political structure involved a meta-institution that was flexible enough to change and adapt to the new world. This function was filled by the British parliament, a place where different interest groups met, bargained and compromised within certain prespecified rules. Although considered a highly imperfect democratic institution by current standards, not least since it only represented the top layer of society (Mokyr, 2009, p. 414), the British parliament provided the type of agility that helped force socially beneficial decisions about new technology over potential losers with incentives to block the process.

The political economy of technological change and knowledge. In his analytical narrative, Mokyr offers many examples of how the process of creative destruction met with fierce resistance to technological change by vested interest groups. One example is the instance where tailors in Cologne, as early as 1397, were prohibited from using machines that pressed pinheads; another is how the city council of Nuremberg, influenced by the guild of red-metal turners, launched an attack in 1561 on a coppersmith by the name of Hans Spaichl who had invented an improved slide rest lathe, threatening to put competitors out of business. Similarly, the inventor of the ribbon loom in Danzig in 1579 was reportedly secretly drowned by order of the city council, and in the 18th century, John Kay, the inventor of the flying shuttle for mechanized weaving, was harassed by unsettled weavers (Mokyr, 1990a, p. 178–179). There were also many examples of outright anti-machinery agitation, most famously the Luddite riots in 1811–1816 and the Captain Swing Riots of the 1830s, both of which took place in England (Mokyr, 1990a, p. 257). The comparative roles of resistance to new technology in Britain and France during the Industrial Revolution are assessed by Mokyr (1992), who further argued (Mokyr, 1994) that it is these barriers to technological change that account for the observed empirical regularity that no nation has managed to remain technologically creative for more than a historically short period of time, before being overtaken by a new technologically leading nation, a phenomenon referred to as Cardwell’s Law (17).

Similarly, the process connecting propositional and prescriptive knowledge often met with set-backs, time lags, and a large dose of creative destruction. In this process, resistance to new ideas did not only come from established interest groups, but sometimes also from scientists or practitioners; more famous examples include Tycho Brahe’s denial of the Copernican system, Einstein’s resistance to quantum theory, or James Watt’s stubborn refusal to accept the workability of high-pressure engines, but many more instances are detailed by Mokyr (2002, p. 225–226). Yet, with an improved feedback loop between science and technology, new knowledge found a more effective way to transform society. The development of ideas for sterilizing surgical instruments—“one of the simplest and cheapest life-saving ideas in history” (Mokyr, 2002, p. 94)—provides an illustration. The idea is often attributed to Oliver Wendell Holmes and Ignaz Semmelweis in the 1840s, although similar thoughts can be traced back to the late 18th century. Initially, the idea that contaminated matter could be transmitted by physicians was, however, met with so much resistance that Holmes dropped it entirely and Semmelweis decided to leave Vienna in disgrace. It is argued that the opposition mainly came from medical practitioners who found the thought of themselves actively transmitting disease being somewhat of an insult, but another part of the problem was that neither Holmes nor Semmelweis could explain why new sanitary techniques could work. It was not until the 1860s and after the findings of Louis Pasteur and Joseph Lister that the ideas were revived. By then, the epistemic base of knowledge was larger, and statistical and experimental techniques were becoming more effective. By the late 1870s, sanitation recommendations became standard techniques.

2.4.3 Quantitative evidence

In collaborative work, Mokyr has provided a series of tests based on quantitative analysis supporting the core insights about the expansion of scientific knowledge, the practical applications and the connection between them.

A joint evolution of science and technology. Mokyr collected a wealth of qualitative and quantitative evidence of the spread of the Enlightenment through various global institutions for knowledge transmission, such as The Republic of Letters—a long-distance intellectual community involving Europe and the Americas—and the emerging national scientific societies such as The Royal Society in Britain (chartered 1662), the French Academy of Sciences (founded in 1666), the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences (founded in 1739), and many more.

Mokyr (2005a) traced the intellectual origins of the Industrial Revolution in an attempt to quantify the Enlightenment. Based on various sources mentioning enlightened ideas, scientific and technical journals and a database of scholarly societies, Mokyr documents a marked increase in publications and societies, as visualized in Figure 5 (18). Yet, Britain does not stand out as being unusually committed to, or engaged in, the Enlightenment movement. Thus, the quantitative evidence speaks in favor of viewing the Enlightenment as a pan-European phenomenon, gradually taking hold of many Western societies, albeit with different national styles and emphasis in the nature of knowledge spread and creation. Britain’s advantage lay in its abundant supply of mechanical skills, an advantage that was extended during the Continental political upheavals of the Revolutionary and Napoleonic eras. However, European variations in adoption rates were a matter of differences in degree, not in kind. Because of the inherent characteristics of the pan-European Industrial Enlightenment movement, convergence of technology and income materialized with delayed European takeoffs in the 19th century.

Figure 5: Scientific periodicals by year of first appearance

 

Figure notes: Scientific and technical journals published in Europe between 1600 and 1800, by year of first appearance. Source: (Mokyr, 2005a), based on Kronick (1991).

Evidence for the connection between scientific knowledge and practical implementation in Britain has been established in Meisenzahl and Mokyr (2012). The authors collected a new database of British inventors, tweakers and implementers representing successful careers in the early stages of British industrialization. The data were collected from different biographical compendia and cross-checked and complemented with information from the Oxford Dictionary of National Biography and the Alphabetical Index of Patentees of Inventions by Woodcroft (1854). It contains 758 men and one woman born before 1830 who contributed to technological change (the woman was Elenor Coade, who invented a new process for making artificial stone). To be in the sample, they had to have made some inventions themselves (mostly micro inventions and adaptations), but their main activity was tweaking and implementation. Thus, the focus here is not so much the famous inventors known from history text books, but rather the “tweakers” who were able to improve and de-bug existing innovations and the “implementers” capable of building, installing and operating new and complex equipment. Such engineers, mechanics, millwrights, chemists, clock- and instrument makers, skilled carpenters and metal workers constituted the top level of skills-distribution just below the layer of the most famous inventors. With this data, Meisenzahl and Mokyr (2012) showed that new inventions occurred in a broad set of sectors, not just in textiles and metals, and that many inventors were engaged with the scientific community. Above half of the inventors in the sample either published in, or belonged to, scientific or technical societies, and among those more narrowly defined as engineers, the corresponding figure was around two-thirds. However, only 10% of the inventors in textiles, the traditional focus industry of the Industrial Revolution, engaged with such professional societies. The authors also show how the upper-tail human capital among these inventors was formed, as about two-thirds of the tweakers had been apprenticed. However, despite having contributed to important innovations, 40% never took out a patent. With this data, Meisenzahl and Mokyr (2012) concluded that an Enlightened culture was rooted in the top of the skill distribution, and that apprenticeship rather than years of formal schooling played important roles.

Mechanical competence. In understanding Britain’s early advantage over other countries in mechanical competence, two factors stand out: (i) early advantages in metal trades and water-powered machinery, and (ii) an unusually flexible apprentice system that allowed for knowledge creation and industrial applications. Relating to the first, Mokyr et al. (2022) go back to data from the Domesday Book in 1086 to trace the origins of mechanical skills to the adoption of water-powered mills. They argued that the millwrights’ growing competence in construction, maintenance and improvement of the machinery generated an early local advantage for complementary machinery in other industrial uses at the same site. Relating to the second, Mokyr, together with coauthors Kelly and ´O Gr´ada, showed that British laborers in 1750 were far superior to those on the Continent in terms of both physical qualities and technical skills (Kelly et al., 2014). They highlight that while Britain did have higher wages than France, these differences in wages actually reflect differences in human capital and skill. In other words, the English workers were more productive than the French (19).

Finally, a first effort to qualitatively evaluate the many competing explanations for the Industrial Revolution was made by Mokyr with coauthors Kelly and ´O Gr´ada (Kelly et al., 2023). The authors collect data on key variables, including measures of mechanical skills and wages, from 41 English counties between the 1760s and 1830s. Using this data, they examine whether a wide range of factors—wages, artisan skills, access to coal, literacy, financial markets and legal capital—were decisive in early industrialization, and they find that industrialization occurred in areas that began with low wages but high mechanical skills, whereas other variables, such as literacy, banks and proximity to coal, have little explanatory power. Fig-ure 6 demonstrates one of the main takeaways from their data. It plots each county’s textile employment share in 1851 against the mechanical skills in the 1790s (on the left) and the agricultural wages in 1760 (on the right). There is a positive relationship between the pre-Industrial Revolution supply of mechanical skills (measured in the census of 1851 as the share of men over 60 with occupations such as blacksmiths, millwrights, watch- and instrument makers, gunsmiths and locksmiths, toolmakers, sheet-metal workers, and mechanics) and the share of workers in textiles 1851. On the other hand, the relationship with wages is negative (20).

Figure 6: Mechanical skills, wages and industrialization in English counties

 


Figure notes: Left panel: The supply of mechanical skills vs. percentage of males employed in textiles 1851. Right panel agricultural wages in the 1760s vs. percentage of males employed in textiles 1851, logarithmic axes. Source: Kelly et al. (2023).

2.5 Empirical follow-up studies

Connecting the scientific and industrial revolutions, Kelly and ´O Gr´ada (2022) showed how the diffusion of numerical skills supplied Britain with a pool of mechanically skilled labor to build the increasingly complicated machinery of the late 18th century. They also showed that the revolutionary innovations in machine tools drew on a technology of exact measurement developed for navigational and astronomical instruments. Figure 7 establishes that strong connections between science and technology led to the success of the English instrument industry relative to its less adaptable French counterpart. A similar connection to the spread of useful knowledge has been quantitatively established in Galofr´e-Vil`a (2023) who found that British counties with a relatively high number of informal networks—in the form of Freemasonry, friendly societies, libraries, and booksellers—experienced more innovation as measured by new patents or exhibits at the 1851 Crystal Palace World’s Fair.

Across Europe, Squicciarini and Voigtl¨ander (2015) found that the Enlightenment reduced costs of accessing useful knowledge and influenced economic growth in 18th and 19th century France, and Cinnirella et al. (2024) found that economic societies led to more innovative activities in 19th century Germany. Although the focus on France and Germany does not permit the authors to say anything about the origins of the British Industrial Revolution, these studies test the main idea about the Enlightenment being a pan-European phenomenon influencing useful knowledge and economic growth, once other barriers were removed.

Figure 7: Number of instrument makers by decade

 


Figure notes: Known English and French makers of mathematical and other instruments by decade. Source: Kelly and ´O Gr´ada (2022) building on the Webster Signatures Database.

Studies by De Pleijt et al. (2020), and Hanlon (2025) have further quantitatively established the role of skilled workers and engineers sustaining the British Industrial Revolution, whereas the role of engineers in global economic growth has been documented for the U.S. (county-level) and at national levels for the 18 Americas during the Second Industrial Revolution (1870–1914) by Maloney and Valencia Caicedo (2022). Finally, few quantitative studies document causal evidence of popular resistance on technological change. An exception is Caprettini and Voth (2020), who collect data on threshing machine diffusion and show that labor-saving technology was associated with more riots among agricultural workers in England during the 1830s.

2.6 Scientific impact

History is rarely monocausal. It is likely that several causes for main events can be present at the same time. Different theories, moreover, are not necessarily contradictory but, rather, complementary. The debate about the Industrial Revolution and its causes is broad and abounds with alternative factors and explanations. It is probable that many conditions interacted to create the specific chain of events unfolding when Britain emerged as the world’s first industrial nation. Today, however, it is widely accepted that any explanation for a sustained acceleration of productivity growth must come from “understanding the development and subsequent incremental improvement of new technologies” (Crafts, 2011, p. 166). With a novel framework that put technology at the center, Mokyr changed how the field viewed the onset of modern economic growth. Instead of seeing technology as the residual from everything we can measure (e.g., Solow (1957)), Mokyr introduced a new perspective, focusing exactly on explaining technology and the necessary requirements needed for technology to feed into sustained growth. By emphasizing the broad societal and technological changes that took place during and after the Enlightenment, Mokyr’s work reintroduced the “revolution” into the Industrial Revolution. Contrary to those seeing the period as a gradual structural transformation, Mokyr emphasized the transformational character of growth rates that were sustained over the longer run, even though their magnitudes were at first sluggish. Pioneering and documenting the resistance to technological change, Mokyr also integrated the political economy of technological change into the historical debate, and stimulated further economic models in this vein. Mokyr’s novel explanation went beyond the combination of existing growth theories, and the common search for country-specific factors. Aiming to account both for the long-term pre-industrial stagnation, as well as the timing and place of the Industrial Revolution, his work connected economic history with history of technology and science and shifted the focus from country-specific pre-conditions to global comparisons. In focusing on relevant macro comparisons between Western Europe and China, Mokyr was ahead of his time. Many comparative ideas were later developed and discussed by the so-called California School, which challenged conventional views on the Great Divergence and emphasized the need for a more global and contextual approach to economic history (see for example Frank (1998), or Pomeranz (2000)). The macro comparisons and fundamental questions asked by Mokyr have influenced several fields in economics, such as development economics, growth theory, and macroeconomics who have benefited from integrating large (“Big Think”) arguments into their studies. As a result, undergraduate and graduate courses in economics now include books and papers that discuss Mokyr’s ideas in their curricula and recent work on how various aspects of long-run growth relate to and engage with his work (see for example Johnson and Acemoglu (2023) or Aghion et al. (2021)). In recent standard textbooks, Mokyr’s work is a main reference on the topic of Industrial Revolutions and the causes of sustained modern economic growth (see for example Blum and Colvin (2018), Persson and Sharp (2025), or Koyama and Rubin (2022)).

3 Creative destruction and growth

While Mokyr studied the takeoff of growth during the Industrial Revolution and the lack of sustained growth prior to this event, Aghion and Howitt were motivated by the remarkably stable nature of aggregate growth in advanced economies over the post World War II period. Aghion and Howitt also noted that technological change is a very disruptive process in which successful innovators enter new markets or expand their production, but do so by making older products obsolete and by (partially) stealing business from incumbent firms. Hence, Aghion and Howitt’s analysis was motivated by how they perceived innovation to actually take place, and to this end, they set out to provide a theoretical framework for studying this process. It was far from obvious whether and how an endogenous growth theory that features business stealing, creative destruction, and entry and exit at the micro level can be squared with the remarkably balanced picture of growth at the aggregate macro level. Aghion and Howitt (1992) reconciled the seemingly contradictory micro and macro observations and demonstrated how the theory could be used to address normative policy questions. The 1992 paper marked a paradigm shift in the growth literature. At its core, the theory features a rich interplay between competition and innovation, which allowed Aghion and Howitt to connect the literature on macroeconomic growth with the field of industrial organization—a connection that proved to be extremely fertile. The model Aghion and Howitt constructed had a number of predictions for firms that were borne out in the data; the theory also turned out to be amenable to countless extensions and generalizations, thereby generating a large amount of follow-up research. Below, we begin by motivating the concept of “creative destruction” empirically and showing how it is linked to economic growth. We continue by commenting on the point of departure in the literature to which Aghion and Howitt’s work belongs. We then lay out the basic theoretical mechanism and comment on empirical follow-up studies and the policy relevance of their work.

3.1 Motivating evidence

Advanced economies are very dynamic, i.e., growth goes hand in hand with the continuous process of entry, exit, and churning of production factors across production units. The theory by Aghion and Howitt (1992) makes a connection between this disruptive process and the aggregate growth rate of technological change. In this section we document in U.S. micro data the scale of this process of creative destruction and how it is connected to growth—the main study object of Aghion and Howitt (1992). Figure 8 shows firm entry and exit rates and the rates of job creation and destruction in the U.S. In a typical year more than 10% of firms either enter or exit the market. The reallocation rate of production 20 factors across establishments—measured in Figure 8 as job creation and destruction rates—is high too, suggesting a continuous reallocation of jobs among incumbent firms.

Figure 8: Dynamism in the U.S.

Data Source: Business Dynamics Statistics. The figure shows 5-year averages of the annual firm entry, firm exit, and job creation and destruction rates in percent. The green line shows the job creation rate, i.e., the number of jobs created by entering or expanding establishments relative to the total number of jobs. The orange line is the average annual job destruction rate, i.e., the number of
jobs “lost” by exiting or shrinking establishments relative to the total number of jobs.

The vast majority of the churning happens within narrowly defined industries as opposed to being associated with a secular shift of economic activity between sectors (see Davis and Haltiwanger (1992) and Davis et al. (1996)). Figure 9 shows the correlation across 4-digit industries between various measures of dynamism averaged over the years 1980–2022. In industries where the firm entry rate is high, the firm exit rate is high too (see Figure 9a). Industries that show a high rate of job destruction also show a high rate of job creation (see Figure 9b). Figure 9c documents a positive correlation of firm entry rates with the establishment exit rate. This moves us closer to the notion of a product cycle, as the closing down of an establishment may be viewed as a proxy for product market exit (21). Finally, Figure 9d shows that a higher firm entry rate is not only associated with higher exit but also with a higher job destruction rate for surviving incumbents. The literature has documented a range of additional empirical facts beyond the patterns shown here, e.g., that exit rates fall with firm age, that plants and firms grow in size over their lifecycle conditional on survival, and the large differences in firm size within narrowly defined industries (see Haltiwanger et al. (2013), Decker et al. (2014), and Hsieh and Klenow (2014)). These facts are also well established in economies other than the U.S. (see Bartelsman and Doms (2000), Ahn (2001), and Bartelsman et al. (2004) for survey evidence).

 Figure 9: Measures of dynamism across U.S. industries, 1980–2022 

 

 

Data source: Business Dynamics Statistics. The sample consists of different four-digit industries. Different two-digit sectors are highlighted by different colors.

Figure 10: Labor productivity growth vs. measures of dyanamism, 1988–2022 


The figures show binned-scatter plots of 5-year averages by industry in firm exit rates or job destruction rates vs. the 5-year averages of labor productivity growth rates. The sample consists of 159 four-digit industries and seven 5-year periods. The figures are inspired by a similar analysis in Adhami (2025). Data source: Business Dynamics Statistics for dynamism variables and BLS for labor productivity growth.

 

The empirical appeal of the creative destruction paradigm is that it not only speaks to the evidence on firm dynamics but connects the facts in Figure 9 to growth and technological change. Figure 10 shows, in binned scatterplots, that both the 5-year-industry average in firm exit rates and the job destruction rates are positively related to labor productivity growth (22). Foster et al. (2001) and Bartelsman and Doms (2000) attribute about one quarter of average total factor productivity growth to entry and exit—and this number is estimated to be even higher in Lentz and Mortensen (2008)—while the remaining productivity improvements are accounted for by continuing plants. Garcia-Macia et al. (2019) use various moments of job reallocation across firms as well as entry and exit rates, to infer the contributions of different types of innovations; based on the data, they argue that creative destruction plays an important role. Finally, Baqaee and Farhi (2020) calculate that roughly half of aggregate U.S. total factor productivity growth over the period 1997–2015 is due to the reallocation of production factors from low to high revenue productivity firms. Even at the aggregate time series level, measures of dynamism (i.e., entry, exit, and rates of job churning) are correlated with economic growth in the U.S. and in other advanced economies. Figure 8 reveals a pattern of declining dynamism since the mid-2000s (23). This period is indeed characterized by a productivity growth slowdown; more recent literature connects the two phenomena through the prism of creative destruction (see, e.g., Decker et al. (2016), Akcigit and Ates (2021), Aghion et al. (2023), and Akcigit and Ates (2023)). In Section 3.3 we present the basic theory of growth through creative destruction as introduced by Aghion and Howitt (1992). Before we do so, we comment on how their contribution is embedded in the literature.

3.2 Points of departure

The observation that economic growth of advanced economies is ultimately driven by technological change as opposed to factor accumulation goes back to at least Solow’s work (Solow, 1956, 1957). As a conse-quence, much research has followed Solow’s original contribution, and focused on how to measure tech-nological change and how economies accumulate physical and human capital as a result of technological change.

The question of what drives technological change itself was not formally addressed until the early 1990s, when Paul Romer began to formulate theories around knowledge accumulation through purpose-ful innovation and emphasized key attributes such as the non-rival nature of ideas (see Romer (1990)). Older versions of endogenous growth models were instead solely based on physical and human capital accumulation, with the potential addition of externalities (see Romer (1986) and Lucas Jr (1988)). The theoretical literature that connects the aggregate growth rate to purposeful R&D investments took longer to emerge because it is far from obvious how competitive forces play out in the market for ideas, such as blueprints for new products, and how this process can be modeled in general equilibrium. A key the-oretical building block that allowed the innovation-led growth literature to take off was marked by the framework of monopolistic competition (Dixit and Stiglitz (1977)). Romer modeled the rate of technolog-ical change as the addition of new product varieties that complement all preexisting products. But major theoretical obstacles remained, and in its infancy, the literature on innovation-led growth remained rather theoretical and abstract; its efforts were arguably mainly driven by intellectual curiosity and conceptual challenges.

Aghion and Howitt were at the forefront of this early literature, but were motivated by the additional observation that at the more microeconomic level, i.e., the industry, firm, and product level, growth is not balanced at all. The process is instead characterized by a highly disruptive nature with entry, exit, and churning (see Section 3.1). In reality, innovations do not magically lift all boats but—despite being overall socially beneficial—systematically generate winners and losers. By explicitly modeling the disruptive na-ture of growth and technological change, where successful innovations replace older products and destroy the rents of incumbent firms, Aghion and Howitt (1992) introduced the notion of creative destruction into the theoretical literature on endogenous growth and showed how it still can be squared with a sustained balanced growth path in the aggregate.
The concept of creative destruction is also tightly linked to Joseph Schumpeter, who described the relentless innovation and entry of new entrepreneurs as the key driver of aggregate growth (see in Schum-peter (1942)) (24). In sharp contrast to Schumpeter, who saw creative destruction as the seed of an in-evitable demise of free-market economies, Aghion and Howitt demonstrated how creative destruction-driven growth can actually be sustained, and not slow down, as had been the case before the Industrial Revolution. In parallel, Segerstrom et al. (1990) characterized a model with some features in common with the model of Aghion and Howitt (1992)—innovations build on each other and therefore eclipse previous ones—and applied the model to study international trade between poor and rich countries (25). The paper by Aghion and Howitt (1992) was key in opening up the field by establishing the creative destruction paradigm and demonstrating its potential for both positive and normative analyses of aggregate growth. The resulting framework turned out to be amenable to extensions, was quickly adopted (see, e.g., Grossman and Helpman (1991b) for an early adoption), and generated a large body of literature that followed in Aghion and Howitt’s footsteps. Aghion and Howitt built on the industrial organization literature on patent races (see, e.g., Loury (1979), Lee and Wilde (1980), and Reinganum (1985)). Unlike Romer (1990), this literature typically models innovations to be uncertain and to be substitutes rather than complements to each other, such that a successful innovation eclipses the effort of a competitor. A key theoretical challenge Aghion and Howitt overcame was to incorporate the mechanisms studied in industrial organization—which rely on strategic interactions—into general equilibrium. How can the conflicting interests be squared with the remarkably balanced picture of growth at the aggregate level? Aghion and Howitt provided an answer in their 1992 paper, used the framework to discuss normative questions, and extended the mechanism to capture strategic interactions in follow-up work (see Aghion et al. (2001)). As a result, Aghion and Howitt’s contribution has allowed the macroeconomic literature on growth to be merged with the industrial organization literature on R&D and competition.

3.3 A basic framework of growth through creative destruction

This section specifies the basic framework of growth through creative destruction as introduced by Aghion and Howitt (1992). We first outline the so-called firm problem in partial equilibrium and show how the future threat of creative destruction influences the value of an incumbent firm. We then illustrate how this building block can be integrated into a general equilibrium analysis to explain the long-run growth rate of the aggregate economy. Finally, we contrast the decentralized equilibrium with the so-called planner’s solution in order to comment on policy.

3.3.1 The profit and value function of a monopolist in partial equilibrium

Consider a monopolist with a perpetual patent to produce a good ν at a quality level q(ν). Suppose that, in each period t, the downward-sloping demand function for the good reads as follows... 

(For more details on this sections, please read the original source).

 3.4 Next theoretical steps and applications of the basic framework

The building blocks underlying the simple model above have proven to have far-reaching theoretical implications while still remaining tractable. As a result, the basic mechanism introduced by Aghion and Howitt (1992) has been further developed and successfully applied to a variety of questions in follow-up research by the laureates themselves and many others. Here we discuss such important next theoretical steps.

Market structure. The baseline model above is embedded in a monopolistic competition setting and does not feature strategic interactions across firms. Important efforts therefore aimed to generalize the framework in this respect, to capture richer interactions between innovation and competition. This crucial step was undertaken in Aghion et al. (1997, 2001). As in the basic model above, there is still a unit interval of product markets but within each product market, two firms are producing imperfect substitutes and compete `a la Bertrand (or Cournot). With imperfect substitutes and oligopolistic competition, both firms will stay in the market and produce. A firm with a productivity edge over its competitor will, however, produce more and can charge a higher markup. Justified by some tacit knowledge in R&D, innovations of the two firms are then assumed to take place step by step as opposed to by leapfrogging. This means that each firm climbs its own productivity ladder; i.e., a firm that is lagging behind has to catch up rung-by-rung and cannot directly overtake the leading firm by building on its rival’s productivity. This framework results in very rich interactions between competition and innovation. On the one hand, the productivity gap between the two firms crucially determines markups and the incentive to invest in R&D. On the other hand, the equilibrium distribution of productivity gaps across product markets depends on the innovation incentives and the implied R&D activity of the two firms.

Using such a framework, Aghion et al. (2001) studied how changes in the substitutability of products affect the innovation incentive and in turn aggregate growth. A higher substitutablility of the products implies a higher level of competition and generally lower level of profits. However, it also changes the steepness of the firm’s value function in the productivity gap and therefore its incentive to innovate. When the two firms have the same productivity, i.e., are neck-to-neck, then the higher the elasticity of substitution, the higher the incentive to invest in R&D in order to become a leader. This is the so-called escape competition effect: neck-to-neck firms have a particularly high incentive to innovate if the product market competition is fierce. In contrast, for firms clearly lagging behind their competitors, the so-called Schumpeterian effect kicks in. In particular, for such a lagging firm, the steep section of the value function (at the point when it may overtake the leading firm) is far in the future. As a consequence, given sufficient time discounting, lagging firms are discouraged to innovate, and it can be shown that a laggard’s innovation incentive falls in the substitutablility of the products. Finally, as the long-run equilibrium distribution of productivity gaps is endogenous and the innovation incentive differs between markets that are neck-to-neck and markets with a productivity gap, there is also a compositional effect. This type of step-by-step innovation setup can generate the prediction of a non-monotonic relationship between product market competition and innovation. This framework has been widely applied in the follow-up literature to study the interplay between innovation, patent protection, and competition (see Aghion et al. (2001), Aghion et al. (2005), Acemoglu and Akcigit (2012), and Akcigit and Ates (2023) to name a few).

Technological waves. The innovations studied in the baseline framework are what Mokyr describes as micro inventions. Follow-up work extended the theory by Aghion and Howitt to study macro inventions or general purpose technologies as described by Bresnahan and Trajtenberg (1995). Such versions of the theory can be used to study technological waves and their effect on inequality (see Helpman and Trajtenberg (1994) and Aghion et al. (2002)).

Firm heterogeneity. The basic creative destruction mechanism in the baseline model generates significant firm heterogeneity. The model features conflicting interests, entry and exit of firms, and a product lifecycle of stochastic length. A general theme of the subsequent literature was to add more heterogeneity in terms of competition (as discussed above) or in terms of R&D technology. In the basic framework of Section 3.3, for simplicity, the innovation technology is assumed to feature constant returns to scale. In contrast, Aghion and Howitt (1992) and a large body of follow-up literature entertain convex innovation costs, which will pin down the equilibrium R&D effort of each individual entrepreneur or firm. Such a setting has often been augmented with heterogeneity in R&D costs or in the innovation step sizes (see, e.g., Luttmer (2011), Akcigit and Kerr (2018), Acemoglu et al. (2018), and Aghion et al. (2023)). Combined with richer market structures (as discussed above), this kind of addition allows us to study the interplay between incumbents and entrants, old and young, small and large, and growing and shrinking firms, all in a market economy with conflicting interests.

Innovations by incumbents. Because of the Arrow replacement effect, in the basic model of the previous section, all innovations are carried out by new entrants. In reality, however, large incumbent firms do systematically improve on their products over time, and the literature has come up with various ways of adding such incumbent own-innovation to the basic framework. The step-by-step innovation framework of Aghion et al. (2001) features incumbent firms improving their own products. Klette and Kortum (2004) added multi-product firms, which innovate to expand into new product markets. In Akcigit and Kerr (2018), firms can increase sales by improving their own products and do so as a result of convex R&D cost with low initial marginal cost of innovation. As modified by Peters (2020), firms have incentives to improve on their own products, as this allows them to increase the markup on their products (therefore boosting their profits).

Firm dynamics. In models of firm heterogeneity, size distribution and firm dynamics are generated by different firm-level productivities and changes therein (see Jovanovic (1982), Hopenhayn (1992), Melitz (2003)). In the data, we observe firms that downsize (and exit) very rapidly, suggesting that some firms must have been hit by large negative shocks. Creative destruction theory offers a very powerful and persuasive explanation: firms that see their product markets eclipsed by an innovation of a competitor rapidly lose business and might even be forced to exit.35 The building block pioneered by Aghion and Howitt therefore found a powerful application in models of firm dynamics. This extended the pioneering work on firm heterogeneity carried out by others by providing deeper explanations for the idiosyncratic productivity changes that drive firm dynamics in those models. Furthermore, such application of the framework by Aghion and Howitt allows for predictions of the long-run firm size distribution, market concentration, and market power. Klette and Kortum’s (2004) paper was key in making this connection, and many others, such as Lentz and Mortensen (2008), followed suit. This line of research has sparked further activity that continues to grow, where the aims are more quantitative—i.e., trying to match not only qualitative features of the data but also their magnitudes—than in the earlier literature (see, e.g., Luttmer (2011), Atkeson and Burstein (2019), Akcigit and Kerr (2018), or Acemoglu et al. (2018)). This current research in the field also blends in other innovation mechanisms such as variety expansion (Romer, 1990) or the notion that ideas are harder and harder to find (Jones, 1995; Bloom et al., 2020); in all of this work, the element of creative destruction remains central in matching the observed firm dynamics.36

3.5 Empirical follow-up studies

The emergence of the theory of creative destruction stimulated applied research in the field, greatly ex-panding the literature testing the theory’s predictions in the data. This endeavor relied heavily on microe-conomic industry-, firm-, plant- and product-level data. The creative destruction paradigm features sig-nificant asymmetric effects across firms within markets (entry vs. exit, expansion vs. downsizing), which cannot be tested in aggregate data. Thus, to confront the theory, and its most important predictions, with data would have to involve microeconomic detail. More generally, as growth rates of advanced economies were remarkably stable over time, one has to rely on more disaggregated data to test and discipline growth theories quantitatively. The theoretical advances in the area of creative destruction also fell on fertile ground: large administrative datasets on firms, patents (see Griliches (1998) and Hall et al. (2001)), and products became more and more readily available, and these data could be linked to, e.g., background information on inventors and entrepreneurs (Bell et al. (2019) and Aghion et al. (2017)). In the following, we briefly mention some of these empirical follow-up studies that demonstrated both the empirical validity and relevance of the creative destruction paradigm. The relationship between competition and innovation. Models of endogenous growth that do not fea-ture creative destruction predict growth and product market competition to be negatively related to each other: big upfront R&D investments must be incentivized by high markups. The step-by-step innovation models developed by Aghion et al. (1997, 2001) can break this strong theoretical prediction that is typically not borne out in the data: Nickell (1996), Blundell et al. (1995), and Blundell et al. (1999) provide empirical evidence pointing rather to a positive relationship between innovation and product market competition. Aghion et al. (2005) document an inverse U relationship between competition and innovation and show how the theory can generate such a pattern.37 More competition may foster growth in frontier firms but discourages it in non-frontier firms. At the same time, competition decreases the fraction of markets with neck-to-neck firms, implying—through a compositional effect—that innovations eventually fall in the level of competition. Aghion et al. (2005) also show empirical support for these auxiliary predictions.

Firm dynamics. A large applied literature investigated the relentless process of entry, exit, expansion, and downscaling of firms and its connection to economic growth. Davis and Haltiwanger (1992) and Davis et al. (1996) document a large rate of job creation and destruction in the U.S. economy within narrowly defined industries (in part illustrated in Section 3.1), and Haltiwanger et al. (2013) and Hsieh and Klenow (2014) show how firms grow over their lifecycle conditional on survival. These patterns can be replicated by the type of model by Klette and Kortum. Empirical moments of firm dynamism were successfully used to discipline and quantify endogenous growth theories that feature creative destruction. A key question this literature addresses is how much entrant vs. incumbent, large vs. small, and young vs. old firms, or different type of innovations, contribute to aggregate output growth (see Foster et al. (2001), Lentz and Mortensen (2008), Bartelsman and Doms (2000), Luttmer (2011), Akcigit and Kerr (2018), Atkeson and Burstein (2019), and Garcia-Macia et al. (2019)).

Recent macroeconomic trends. Productivity growth rates in advanced economies remained remarkably stable over time for most of the post World War II period. However, since the 2000s, OECD countries have witnessed a significant slowdown of productivity growth (Figure 11 illustrates labor productivity). The same period was characterized by a fall in labor’s share of total income, and additional evidence points to rising markups (see Akcigit and Ates (2021) for a summary). Absent a mechanism of creative destruction, it is typically not possible to square these observations. Over recent years, many of the advanced economies also saw falling firm entry and exit rates and declining job reallocation rates, which is corroborating evidence that the productivity slowdown was indeed accompanied by a reduction in creative destruction (for the U.S. see Figure 8 and the evidence in Decker et al. (2014)). Recent quantitative work investigates the reasons behind the productivity growth slowdown through the lens of an innovation-led growth model in the spirit of Aghion and Howitt (see, e.g., Aghion et al. (2023), Akcigit and Ates (2023), and De Ridder (2024)).

3.6 Policy relevance
The creative destruction paradigm has direct policy implications. At its core, there is the prediction of a rich interplay—with a possible non-monotonic relationship—between competition and innovation. Un-

Models developed by Aghion et al. (1997, 2001) can break this strong theoretical prediction that is typically not borne out in the data: Nickell (1996), Blundell et al. (1995), and Blundell et al. (1999) provide empirical evidence pointing rather to a positive relationship between innovation and product market competition. Aghion et al. (2005) document an inverse U relationship between competition and innovation and show how the theory can generate such a pattern.37 More competition may foster growth in frontier firms but discourages it in non-frontier firms. At the same time, competition decreases the fraction of markets with neck-to-neck firms, implying—through a compositional effect—that innovations eventually fall in the level of competition. Aghion et al. (2005) also show empirical support for these auxiliary predictions.

Firm dynamics. A large applied literature investigated the relentless process of entry, exit, expansion, and downscaling of firms and its connection to economic growth. Davis and Haltiwanger (1992) and Davis et al. (1996) document a large rate of job creation and destruction in the U.S. economy within narrowly defined industries (in part illustrated in Section 3.1), and Haltiwanger et al. (2013) and Hsieh and Klenow (2014) show how firms grow over their lifecycle conditional on survival. These patterns can be replicated by the type of model by Klette and Kortum. Empirical moments of firm dynamism were successfully used to discipline and quantify endogenous growth theories that feature creative destruction. A key question this literature addresses is how much entrant vs. incumbent, large vs. small, and young vs. old firms, or different type of innovations, contribute to aggregate output growth (see Foster et al. (2001), Lentz and Mortensen (2008), Bartelsman and Doms (2000), Luttmer (2011), Akcigit and Kerr (2018), Atkeson and Burstein (2019), and Garcia-Macia et al. (2019)).

Recent macroeconomic trends. Productivity growth rates in advanced economies remained remarkably stable over time for most of the post World War II period. However, since the 2000s, OECD countries have witnessed a significant slowdown of productivity growth (Figure 11 illustrates labor productivity). The same period was characterized by a fall in labor’s share of total income, and additional evidence points to rising markups (see Akcigit and Ates (2021) for a summary). Absent a mechanism of creative destruction, it is typically not possible to square these observations. Over recent years, many of the advanced economies also saw falling firm entry and exit rates and declining job reallocation rates, which is corroborating evidence that the productivity slowdown was indeed accompanied by a reduction in creative destruction (for the U.S. see Figure 8 and the evidence in Decker et al. (2014)). Recent quantitative work investigates the reasons behind the productivity growth slowdown through the lens of an innovation-led growth model in the spirit of Aghion and Howitt (see, e.g., Aghion et al. (2023), Akcigit and Ates (2023), and De Ridder (2024)).

3.6 Policy relevance

The creative destruction paradigm has direct policy implications. At its core, there is the prediction of a rich interplay—with a possible non-monotonic relationship—between competition and innovation. Under cut-throat competition, firms find it hard to recover R&D through future profits and growth will be low. At the other end of the spectrum, uncontested monopolists typically have low incentive to innovate too. Generally, entrenched incumbents will have a tendency to block entry and hinder growth possibly with the help of government policies. Below, we briefly mention policy aspects that tightly tie in with the theoretical concept of creative destruction introduced by Aghion and Howitt.

 Figure 11: Labor productivity growth in OECD countries
 
 

Source: Penn World Table 10.01. Five-year centered moving average of the yearly labor productivity growth rate across OECD countries. Averages across countries are weighted by real GDP. This is an updated version of figure 10.2 from Boppart and Li (2023).
 

Competition and innovation policy. An important message is the fact that the creative destruction paradigm can generate a non-monotonic relationship between competition and innovation. The message that innovation and competition policies are inherently linked, and that they cannot be studied in isolation, is deeply engrained in today’s antitrust policies or in considerations of R&D subsidies (see, e.g., Furman et al. (2019), Stigler Committee on Digital Platforms (2019), Nadler and Cicilline (2020), or Crémer et al. (2019)). The element of creative destruction is also indispensable for the analysis of optimal patent policy (Acemoglu and Akcigit (2012)).

Suboptimal R&D investments. A natural question is whether the decentralized growth rate is too high or too low, as the latter possibility can arise in models of creative destruction due to the business stealing effect. At the aggregate level, the available evidence clearly points to growth being too low compared to the social optimum (see Jones and Williams (1998), Jones and Williams (2000) and Atkeson and Burstein 36 (2019)). This, however, is still consistent with some industries or firms spending too much on R&D precisely because of the business stealing effect (see, e.g., Aghion et al. (2022)). This suggests that one-size-fits-all R&D subsidies are suboptimal.

Winners, losers, and social insurance. To attain an economy’s full growth potential, production factors have to continuously flow to their most productive use. The creative destruction paradigm suggests that higher growth goes hand in hand with increased business dynamism. What societal conflicts arise as a result of this dynamism? As pointed out above, the baseline model of creative destruction features a representative consumer, so that although firms are in conflict between each other, what matters for people’s welfare is just aggregate consumption. This is of course a drastic simplification: in reality, different consumer and worker groups are influenced by competition and income is shifted between them. The literature has studied such conflicts of interest as well. 

A specific focus has been placed on the labor market. In particular, as a consequence of increased dynamism, the job separation rate is elevated in high-growth periods and industries. In a frictional labor market, this may result in a higher unemployment rate (Aghion and Howitt (1994)). Hence, there is a role for policy to insure unemployed workers who have seen their jobs being creatively destroyed by competitors, and to retrain them so that they find new employment in expanding firms and industries. Such a social insurance system is reminiscent of the “flexicurity” system as introduced by Denmark and the Netherlands in the 1990s. The social welfare state may also be important to secure broad support in society for policies that lead to growth but also unchain the forces of creative destruction. Aghion et al. (2016) show empirical evidence that—after controlling for the unemployment rate—the rate of creative destruction (as measured by job turnover) correlates positively with subjective well-being across different metropolitan statistical areas of the U.S. Furthermore, Aghion et al. (2016) show that the more generous the unemployment benefits, the less negatively associated the rate of job destruction is with subjective well-being.

Tapping into the entire pool of talents. The creative destruction model suggests that the actions of inventors and entrepreneurs are crucial and ultimately determine the long-run growth rate of an economy. As a consequence, human capital and the selection of who becomes an inventor have far-reaching consequences. It is important not to restrict the pool of potential entrants and to make sure that the available entrepreneurs direct their activity to the most productive use (see Baumol (1996) and Aghion and Howitt (1996)). As Aghion et al. (2019) show, measures of social mobility are indeed positively related to growth across U.S. commuting zones. At the same time, high top income inequality—if based on innovation rents—may have to be tolerated in order to incentivize entrepreneurs and inventors to undertake their innovative activities (see Jones and Kim (2018) and Aghion et al. (2019)). In this sense (static) income inequality and social mobility may both stimulate innovations and growth. 

4 Conclusions and implications for society

Over the past 250 years, the world has seen more economic growth than ever before in human history. The driving force behind this process is technological change. This year’s laureates explain the period of sustained economic growth through the same paradigm: growth fueled by the forces of innovation, disruptive on the microeconomic level but still consistent with sustained aggregate growth. 

The laureates studied this process of creative destruction and of the feedback between science and applied technology in detail and show how it allows us to escape the fate of diminishing returns, and leads to sustained economic growth. The literature points to looming threats on the horizon regarding future technological change. Furthermore, measured productivity growth has already slowed down somewhat over the past decades. Some scholars argue that the world has already seen history’s greatest innovations and is doomed to a future of stagnation (e.g., Gordon (2017)). Yet others warn about the disruptive effects from ongoing digitization and automation on the future of work (e.g., Frey and Osborne (2017)), or the erosion of democratic values (e.g., Johnson and Acemoglu (2023)). In addition, major concerns relate to the environmental transition and how to square economic growth with the physical boundaries coming from finite natural resources. Sustained growth is clearly not equal to sustainable growth, as the negative externalities from increased production pose serious strains on our planet. With a science and technology-focused view, however, social and environmental challenges should set into motion searches for novel techniques to address them, so that the technological process itself may be interpreted as a self-correcting process (Mokyr, 2018b, p. 21). Naturally, the time lags and losses involved in such a process might be substantial, giving rise to negative attitudes towards the process of technological change, or what popularly may be regarded as mostly “destructive creation.” 

A positive upshot is that advancing technologies, such as artificial intelligence (AI), bring a new era of data science that could impact overall science much beyond large-scale calculations and standard statistical analysis. Mokyr’s work highlights that technologies holding the potential to enlarge the propositional knowledge base, and simultaneously decrease the costs for practitioners to access available knowledge, may improve the feedback loops between propositional and prescriptive knowledge. Equipped with more powerful tools, our understanding of natural processes may accelerate and new applications, some imaginable and some not, will continue to appear. 

The work by Aghion and Howitt provides us with the theoretical framework to systematically think about the key determinants of the long-run rate of technological change. One such determinant is the competitive environment. An argument, fundamentally based on Aghion and Howitt’s work is that increased firm concentration and market power may be an important factor behind the more recent negative productivity trends. This argument, furthermore, suggests that regulatory oversight is an important part of a policy mix going forward. Relatedly, the nature of technological change in motion right now—driven in large part by AI—is likely to lead to significant structural adjustments and many “losers”, at least in the short run. Supporting those who need help in changing jobs or occupation while not hindering the transition is an important challenge for policymakers. 

Taken together, the work of this year’s laureates help us understand the forces underlying sustained economic growth. Economic stagnation, not growth, has been the norm in human history, and the role of science, innovation, and creative destruction cannot be overstated in the unprededented economic growth experience since the Industrial Revolution. Thus, while knowledge is currently expanding at a fast rate, societies need to pay attention to potential suppression of pluralism, rising market power, and the risk that established interest groups will block the forces of creative destruction with an adverse effect on economic growth.

______________________________________________ 

Links to explanations in the text: 

(1) A similar pattern of sustained economic growth can be seen since 1800 in other advanced economies (see Appendix Figure A1).

(2) The literature on the causes of the Industrial Revolution is too broad to summarize here. The interested reader is referred to reference textbooks, such as chapter 24 in Blum and Colvin (2018), chapter 6 in Persson and Sharp (2025), chapter 8 in Koyama and Rubin (2022), or the editors introduction in Mokyr (2018a).

(3) See arguments by, e.g., Mathias (1972); McKendrick (1973); Landes (1969). A related point, as argued by Gillispie (1957), was that most scientific endeavors of the time were concerned with topics of limited technological use. Occasional counter-arguments about science’s role in the Industrial Revolution are made by Musson and Robinson (1969) and Jacob (1997). Recently, the notion of a lack of scientific content in the Industrial Revolution has been promoted by Allen (2009).

(4) This view was, however, challenged by the so-called California school that put China at par with Europe until about 1800 (Frank, 1998; Pomeranz, 2000). Lately, new comparative output estimates date the Great Divergence to around 1700; see the work by Broad-berry et al. (2018, 2021).

(5) See Temin (1997) for a summary of the debate.

(6) The term macro invention has become associated with the idea of a general purpose technology (GPT) (Bresnahan and Tra-jtenberg, 1995) since both terms refer to disruptive new technologies with transformative effects. But whereas a GPT must have wide applicafbility to other technologies, a macro invention need only bring about potentially great changes in general. Historical work points to the importance of complementarities between innovations in different types of technologies, where Dahm´en (1950) discusses “development blocks” and Landes (1969), and Rosenberg (1976, 1982) mention complementarities too.

(7) Propositional knowledge contains the observation, cataloging and classification of natural phenomena as well as the establish-ment of regularities and principles and natural laws governing these phenomena. Such a definition includes mathematics insofar as it is used to describe and analyze the regularities of nature. Propositional knowledge is thus episteme, the set of rules, assumptions, and discourses that determine what is considered legitimate knowledge and how it is produced and understood within a specific historical context, and prescriptive knowledge is techne, the arts, skills and crafts in the context of making or doing (Mokyr, 2002, p. 4–5).

(8) This aspect is further elaborated in A Culture of Growth, where Mokyr (2016) digs deeper into the question why the Enlighten-ment took place in Europe. Stressing a pluralist society with a functioning market for ideas in combination with cultural changes taking place 1500–1700, the book offers the prelude to the Enlightenment and the subsequent Industrial Revolution. A parallel cul-tural explanation to the Industrial Revolution can be found by McCloskey (2016), who points towards ideas of “bourgeois dignity and equality” that gave a reason for ordinary people to innovate.

(9) The idea that cultural beliefs are the scaffolds on which institutions are built can be traced back to Greif (1994) and North (2004), but while these authors are primarily interested in the kind of beliefs that people hold about one another, Mokyr (2016) stresses the beliefs people hold about their physical milieu.

(10) The role of institutions adds to the large literature on the importance of institutions for growth associated with, e.g., the 1993 economics Laureate Douglass North and the 2024 economics Laureates Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson, and James Robinson (e.g., North and Thomas (1973); North (2004); Acemoglu et al. (2001)). Acemoglu et al. (2005) and North and Weingast (1989) further stress the role of the British parliament in solving commitment problems and putting constraints on the executive.

(11) The failure of China to undergo an Industrial Revolution has been named the Needham puzzle, after sinologist Joseph Needham, who documented Chinese innovations in several volumes called Science and Civilisation in China, the first one published in 1954.

(12) Within Europe, the Netherlands constitutes a useful comparison, as it was in many ways the most advanced economy in Europe and at the cutting edge of technology before the Industrial Revolution. Mokyr (2000) documents that its leadership became short-lived due to negative feedback loops when the narrow bridge that had been built between those who made and built things and those who explored the regularities of nature became even narrower. Despite high human capital and market-friendly institutions, the Netherlands failed to transform its leadership into an Industrial Revolution. By the middle of the 18th century “it seems that something had gone amiss in the way the Dutch were processing useful knowledge” (Mokyr, 2000, p. 512).

(13) The analytical narrative developed by Mokyr (2009) was critically reviewed by Crafts (2011) in conjunction with the arguments put forward in the analytical narrative developed in the contemporary book by Allen (2009). Crafts concludes, by stating that the explanations may be seen as complementary rather than competing, but added that although the arguments in both books have precursors in the historiography, in the case of Mokyr (2009) these refer to the components of the argument rather than to the synthesis (Crafts, 2011, p. 156).

(14) In particular, Mokyr notes that the Industrial Revolution was not as “industrial” and much less pertaining to “textiles and cotton” than commonly asserted. For instance, chapters 10 and 11 in Mokyr (2009) describe the fundamental changes in the service sectors of the British economy, a process of transformation often overlooked in textbooks and monographs.

(15) Scholars writing about the gradually improved connection between science and technology in the 19th century have mostly argued for a causality running from technology to science (see, e.g., Rosenberg (1976, 1982)). Mokyr (2005a) argues in favour of seeing both science and technology as endogenous to the development of useful knowledge that occurred in Europe after the onset of the Enlightenment.

(16) This aspect of high-tail human capital was a driving cause in British leadership but has often been overlooked by economists focusing on the average schooling or skills in the workforce.

(17) The struggle over technological change has thereafter been formally modelled in economics by, among others, Krusell and Rios-Rull (1996), Parente and Prescott (2002) and Acemoglu and Robinson (2006).

(18) The data in Mokyr (2005a) is based on Kors (2003), Kronick (1991) and a database that relies heavily on the website “Scholarly Societies” collected by the University of Waterloo.

(19) sing annual information on apprenticeships in England between 1710 and 1805 and Vector Autoregression (VAR)-techniques, Mokyr with co authors Zeev and van der Beek also found evidence of an elastic supply of apprentices, sufficiently high to allow a considerable response to demand shocks (Zeev et al., 2017).

(20) These findings are also supported in ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions, which can control for other factors such as market potential and access to coal, as well as the competing stories highlighted above. The results are also robust to specifications that deal with the potential endogeneity of the skill supply—namely that the presence of new industries could have resulted in the in-migration of skill—by instrumenting for skill with the median fee to become an apprentice watch maker in the 1700s. Evidence for the competing, but not mutually exclusive, hypothesis that labor scarcity and high wages were conducive to technology adoption and innovation by, e.g., Allen (2009), has been found by Voth et al. (2023), who document synergies between labor shortages and local skill supply, which combined further increased technology adoption and the rate of productivity improvement along the lines of Kelly et al. (2023).

(21) Bernard et al. (2011) show that manufacturing firms that add establishments also branch out into new industries. For services, Hsieh and Rossi-Hansberg (2023) show that the addition of establishments, which is prominent, allows a firm to penetrate more (local) markets.

(22) Appendix Figure A2 shows similar correlations of other measures of economic dynamism with labor productivity growth.

(23) Calvino et al. (2016) document a comparable declining dynamism in countries other than the U.S. and the harmonized data of 20 countries going back to the year 1998 can be found here. Furthermore, the CompNet platform, that can be found here, provides comparable statistics for 17 European countries.

(24) The Schumpeterian ideas have sparked a rich literature and several schools of thought in economics and neighboring disci-plines, for example the evolutionary or neo-Schumpeterian schools (e.g., Nelson and Winter (1982)). The main aspect discussed here focuses more narrowly on the ideas of how the process of creative destruction can be formalized as the driver of sustained economic growth in the aggregate.

(26) To ensure that so-called “drastic innovations” take place, we make the additional assumption that γ > α− α 1−α . The case of “non-drastic” innovations is discussed further below.


______________________________________________

References

Acemoglu, D. (2008). Introduction to modern economic growth. Princeton, New Jersey, U.S.: Princeton University Press.

Acemoglu, D. and U. Akcigit (2012). Intellectual property rights policy, competition and innovation. Journal of the European Economic Association 10(1), 1–42.

Acemoglu, D., U. Akcigit, H. Alp, N. Bloom, and W. Kerr (2018). Innovation, reallocation, and growth. The American Economic Review 108(11), 3450–3491.

Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J. A. Robinson (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation. The American Economic Review 91(5), 1369–1401.

Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J. A. Robinson (2005). Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth. Volume 1 of Handbook of Economic Growth, Chapter 6, pp. 385–472. Amsterdam, The Netherlands: North-Holland.

Acemoglu, D. and J. A. Robinson (2006). Economic backwardness in political perspective. American Political Science Review 100(1), 115–131.

Adhami, M. (2025). Learning about spillovers from product dynamics. Unpublished working paper.

Aghion, P., U. Akcigit, A. Bergeaud, R. Blundell, and D. H´emous (2019). Innovation and top income inequality. The Review of Economic Studies 86(1), 1–45.

Aghion, P., U. Akcigit, A. Deaton, and A. Roulet (2016). Creative destruction and subjective well-being. The American Economic Review 106(12), 3869–3897.

Aghion, P., U. Akcigit, and P. Howitt (2014). What do we learn from Schumpeterian growth theory? In P. Aghion and S. N. Durlauf (Eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, Volume 2B, pp. 515–563. Amsterdam, The Netherlands: North-Holland.

Aghion, P., U. Akcigit, A. Hyytinen, and O. Toivanen (2017). The social origins of inventors. National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 24110, Cambridge, Massachusetts, U.S.

Aghion, P., C. Antonin, and S. Bunel (2021). The power of creative destruction: Economic upheaval and the wealth of nations. Cambridge, Massachusetts, U.S.: Harvard University Press.

Aghion, P., A. Bergeaud, T. Boppart, P. Klenow, and H. Li (2022). Good rents versus bad rents: R&D misallocation and growth. Unpublished working paper.

Aghion, P., A. Bergeaud, T. Boppart, P. J. Klenow, and H. Li (2023). A theory of falling growth and rising rents. The Review of Economic Studies 90(6), 2675–2702.

Aghion, P., N. Bloom, R. Blundell, R. Griffith, and P. Howitt (2005). Competition and innovation: An inverted-U relationship. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 120(2), 701–728.

Aghion, P., C. Harris, P. Howitt, and J. Vickers (2001). Competition, imitation and growth with step-by-step innovation. The Review of Economic Studies 68(3), 467–492.

Aghion, P., C. Harris, and J. Vickers (1997). Competition and growth with step-by-step innovation: An example. European Economic Review 41(3), 771–782.

Aghion, P. and P. Howitt (1992). A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60(2), 323–351.

Aghion, P. and P. Howitt (1994). Growth and unemployment. The Review of Economic Studies 61(3), 477–494.

Aghion, P. and P. Howitt (1996). Research and development in the growth process. Journal of Economic Growth 1(1), 49–73.

Aghion, P., P. Howitt, and G. L. Violante (2002). General purpose technology and wage inequality. Journal of Economic Growth 7 (4), 315–345.

Ahn, S. (2001). Firm dynamics and productivity growth: A review of micro evidence from OECD countries. OECD Economics Department Working Paper No. 297.

Akcigit, U. and S. T. Ates (2021). Ten facts on declining business dynamism and lessons from endogenous growth theory. The American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 13(1), 257–298.

Akcigit, U. and S. T. Ates (2023). What happened to US business dynamism? Journal of Political Economy 131(8), 2059–2124.

Akcigit, U. and W. R. Kerr (2018). Growth through heterogeneous innovations. Journal of Political Economy 126(4), 1374–1443.

Allen, R. C. (2009). The British industrial revolution in global perspective. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.

Alvarez-Nogal, C. and L. P. De La Escosura (2013). The rise and fall of Spain (1270–1850). The Economic History Review 66(1), 1–37.

Arrow, K. (1962). Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity: Economic and Social Factors, pp. 609–626. Princeton, New Jersey, U.K.: Princeton University Press.

Ashton, T. S. (1948). The industrial revolution 1760–1830. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press.

Atkeson, A. and A. Burstein (2019). Aggregate implications of innovation policy. Journal of Political Economy 127 (6), 2625–2683.

Baqaee, D. R. and E. Farhi (2020). Productivity and misallocation in general equilibrium. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 135(1), 105–163.

Bartelsman, E. J. and M. Doms (2000). Understanding productivity: Lessons from longitudinal microdata. Journal of Economic Literature 38(3), 569–594.

Bartelsman, E. J., J. Haltiwanger, and S. Scarpetta (2004). Microeconomic evidence of creative destruction in industrial and developing countries. IZA Discussion Paper No. 1374.

Baumol, W. J. (1996). Entrepreneurship: Productive, unproductive, and destructive. Journal of Business Venturing 11(1), 3–22.

Bell, A., R. Chetty, X. Jaravel, N. Petkova, and J. Van Reenen (2019). Who becomes an inventor in America? The importance of exposure to innovation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 134(2), 647–713.

Berg, M. and P. Hudson (1992). Rehabilitating the industrial revolution. The Economic History Review 45(1), 24–50.

Bernard, A. B., S. J. Redding, and P. K. Schott (2011). Multiproduct firms and trade liberalization. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 126(3), 1271–1318.

Bloom, N., C. I. Jones, J. Van Reenen, and M. Webb (2020). Are ideas getting harder to find? The American Economic Review 110(4), 1104–1144.

Blum, M. and C. L. Colvin (2018). An Economist’s Guide to Economic History. London, U.K.: Palgrave Studies in Economic History, Palgrave Macmillan.

Blundell, R., R. Griffith, and J. V. Reenen (1995). Dynamic count data models of technological innovation. The Economic Journal 105(429), 333–344.

Blundell, R., R. Griffith, and J. Van Reenen (1999). Market share, market value and innovation in a panel of British manufacturing firms. The Review of Economic Studies 66(3), 529–554.

Boppart, T. and H. Li (2023). Productivity slowdown: Reducing the measure of our ignorance. In U. Akcigit and J. Van Reenen (Eds.), The Economics of Creative Destruction: New Research on Themes from Aghion and Howitt, Chapter 10, pp. 283–305. Cambridge, Massachusetts, U.S: Harvard University Press.

Bresnahan, T. F. and M. Trajtenberg (1995). General purpose technologies ‘engines of growth’? Journal of Econometrics 65(1), 83–108.

Broadberry, S., B. M. Campbell, A. Klein, M. Overton, and B. Van Leeuwen (2015). British economic growth, 1270–1870. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.

Broadberry, S., H. Guan, and D. D. Li (2018). China, Europe, and the great divergence: A study in historical national accounting, 980–1850. The Journal of Economic History 78(4), 955–1000.

Broadberry, S., H. Guan, and D. D. Li (2021). China, Europe, and the great divergence: A restatement. The Journal of Economic History 81(3), 958–974.

Calvino, F., C. Criscuolo, and C. Menon (2016). No country for young firms? Start-up dynamics and national policies. Paris, France: OECD Science, Technology and Industry Policy Papers No. 29.

Caprettini, B. and H.-J. Voth (2020). Rage against the machines: Labor-saving technology and unrest in industrializing England. The American Economic Review: Insights 2(3), 305–320.

Cinnirella, F., E. Hornung, and J. Koschnick (2024). Flow of ideas: Economic societies and the rise of useful knowledge. The Economic Journal, ueae115.

Crafts, N. (2011). Explaining the first industrial revolution: Two views. European Review of Economic History 15(1), 153–168.

Crafts, N. F. R. (1985). British economic growth during the industrial revolution. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press.

Crafts, N. F. R. and C. K. Harley (1992). Output growth and the British industrial revolution: A restatement of the Crafts-Harley view. The Economic History Review, 703–730.

Cr´emer, J., Y.-A. De Montjoye, and H. Schweitzer (2019). Competition policy for the digital era. Brussels, Belgium: Publications Office of the European Union.

Dahm´en, E. (1950). Svensk industriell f¨oretagarverksamhet. Kausalanalys av den industriella utvecklingen 1919–1939. Doctoral dissertation, Department of Economics, Lund University.

Davis, S. J. and J. Haltiwanger (1992). Gross job creation, gross job destruction, and employment reallocation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 107 (3), 819–863.

Davis, S. J., J. Haltiwanger, and S. Schuh (1996). Job creation and job destruction. Cambridge, Massachusetts, U.S.: MIT Press.

de la Escosura, L. P. (2009). Lost decades? Economic performance in post-independence Latin America. Journal of Latin America Studies 41(2), 279–306.

De Pleijt, A., A. Nuvolari, and J. Weisdorf (2020). Human capital formation during the first industrial revolution: Evidence from the use of steam engines. Journal of the European Economic Association 18(2), 829–889.

De Ridder, M. (2024). Market power and innovation in the intangible economy. The American Economic Review 114(1), 199–251.

Deane, P. and W. A. Cole (1962). British economic growth 1688–1959: Trends and structure. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.

Decker, R., J. Haltiwanger, R. Jarmin, and J. Miranda (2014). The role of entrepreneurship in US job creation and economic dynamism. Journal of Economic Perspectives 28(3), 3–24.

Decker, R. A., J. Haltiwanger, R. S. Jarmin, and J. Miranda (2016). Declining business dynamism: What we know and the way forward. The American Economic Review 106(5), 203–207.

Dixit, A. K. and J. E. Stiglitz (1977). Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity. The American Economic Review 67 (3), 297–308.

Foster, L., J. C. Haltiwanger, and C. J. Krizan (2001). Aggregate productivity growth: Lessons from microeconomic evidence. In C. R. Hulten, E. R. Dean, and M. J. Harper (Eds.), New developments in productivity analysis, pp. 303–372. Chicago, Illinois, U.S.: University of Chicago Press.

Fouquet, R. and S. Broadberry (2015). Seven centuries of European economic growth and decline. Journal of Economic Perspectives 29(4), 227–244.

Frank, A. G. (1998). ReOrient: Global economy in the Asian age. Oakland, California, U.S.: University of California Press.

Frey, C. B. and M. A. Osborne (2017). The future of employment: How susceptible are jobs to computerisation? Technological forecasting and social change 114, 254–280.

Furman, J., D. Coyle, A. Fletcher, D. McAuley, and P. Marsden (2019). Unlocking digital competition: Report of the digital competition expert panel. London, U.K.: U.K. Government Publication, HM Treasury.

Galofr´e-Vil`a, G. (2023). The diffusion of knowledge during the British industrial revolution. Social Science History 47 (2), 167–188.

Garcia-Macia, D., C.-T. Hsieh, and P. J. Klenow (2019). How destructive is innovation? Econometrica 87 (5), 1507–1541.

Gillispie, C. (1957). The natural history of industry. Isis 48(4), 398–407.

Gordon, R. (2017). The rise and fall of American growth: The US standard of living since the civil war. Princeton, New Jersey, U.S.: Princeton University Press.

Greif, A. (1994). Cultural beliefs and the organization of society: A historical and theoretical reflection on collectivist and individualist societies. Journal of Political Economy 102(5), 912–950.

Griliches, Z. (1998). Patent statistics as economic indicators: A survey. In R&D and productivity: The econometric evidence, pp. 287–343. Chicago, Illinois, U.S.: University of Chicago Press.

Grossman, G. M. and E. Helpman (1989). Product development and international trade. Journal of Political Economy 97 (6), 1261–1283.

Grossman, G. M. and E. Helpman (1991a). Innovation and growth in the global economy, 1991, pp. xiv, 359. Cambridge, Massachusetts, U.S.: MIT Press.

Grossman, G. M. and E. Helpman (1991b). Quality ladders in the theory of growth. The Review of Economic Studies 58(1), 43–61.

Hall, A. R. (1974). What did the industrial revolution in Britain owe to science? In N. McKendrick (Ed.), Historical Perspectives: Studies in English Thought and Society in Honour of J. H. Plumb, pp. 129–151. London, U.K.: Europa Publications.

Hall, B. H., A. B. Jaffe, and M. Trajtenberg (2001). The NBER patent citation data file: Lessons, insights and methodological tools. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts, U.S.

Haltiwanger, J., R. S. Jarmin, and J. Miranda (2013). Who creates jobs? Small versus large versus young. Review of Economics and Statistics 95(2), 347–361.

Hanlon, W. W. (2025). The rise of the engineer: Inventing the professional inventor during the industrial revolution. The Economic Journal, ueaf023.

Harley, C. K. (1982). British industrialization before 1841: Evidence of slower growth during the industrial revolution. The Journal of Economic History 42(2), 267–289.

Helpman, E. and M. Trajtenberg (1994). A time to sow and a time to reap: Growth based on general purpose technologies. National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 4854, Cambridge, Massachusetts, U.S.

Hopenhayn, H. A. (1992). Entry, exit, and firm dynamics in long run equilibrium. Econometrica 60(5), 1127–1150.

Howitt, P. (1999). Steady endogenous growth with population and R&D inputs growing. Journal of Political Economy 107 (4), 715–730.

Hsieh, C.-T. and P. J. Klenow (2014). The life cycle of plants in India and Mexico. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 129(3), 1035–1084.

Hsieh, C.-T. and E. Rossi-Hansberg (2023). The industrial revolution in services. Journal of Political Economy: Macroeconomics 1(1), 3–42.

Jacob, M. C. (1997). Scientific culture and the making of the industrial West. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press.

Johnson, S. and D. Acemoglu (2023). Power and progress: Our thousand-year struggle over technology and prosperity. London, U.K.: Basic Books.

Jones, C. I. (1995). R&D-based models of economic growth. Journal of Political Economy 103(4), 759–784.

Jones, C. I. and J. Kim (2018). A Schumpeterian model of top income inequality. Journal of Political Economy 126(5), 1785–1826.

Jones, C. I. and J. C. Williams (1998). Measuring the social return to R&D. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 113(4), 1119–1135.

Jones, C. I. and J. C. Williams (2000). Too much of a good thing? The economics of investment in R&D. Journal of Economic Growth 5, 65–85.

Jovanovic, B. (1982). Selection and the evolution of industry. Econometrica 50(3), 649–670.

Kelly, M., J. Mokyr, and C. ´O. Gr´ada (2014). Precocious albion: A new interpretation of the British industrial revolution. Annual Review of Economics 6(1), 363–389.

Kelly, M., J. Mokyr, and C. ´O Gr´ada (2023). The mechanics of the industrial revolution. Journal of Political Economy 131(1), 59–94.

Kelly, M. and C. ´O Gr´ada (2022). Connecting the scientific and industrial revolutions: The role of practical mathematics. The Journal of Economic History 82(3), 841–873.

Klette, T. J. and S. Kortum (2004). Innovating firms and aggregate innovation. Journal of Political Economy 112(5), 986–1018.

Kors, A. C. (2003). Encyclopedia of the Enlightenment. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press.

Koyama, M. and J. Rubin (2022). How the world became rich: The historical origins of economic growth. Hoboken, New Jersey, U.S.: John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

Kronick, D. A. (1991). Scientific and technical periodicals of the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries: A guide. Metuchen, New Jersey, U.S.: Scarecrow Press.

Krusell, P. and J.-V. Rios-Rull (1996). Vested interests in a positive theory of stagnation and growth. The Review of Economic Studies 63(2), 301–329.

Kuznets, S. (1965). Economic Growth and Structure: Selected Essays. New York, U.S.: W. W. Norton & Company.

Landes, D. S. (1969). The unbound Prometheus: Technological change and industrial development in Western Europe from 1750 to the present. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.

Landes, D. S. (1998). Wealth and poverty of nations. New York, U.S.: W. W. Norton & Company.

Lee, T. and L. L. Wilde (1980). Market structure and innovation: A reformulation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 94(2), 429–436.

Lentz, R. and D. T. Mortensen (2008). An empirical model of growth through product innovation. Econometrica 76(6), 1317–1373.

Lin, J. Y. (1995). The needham puzzle: Why the industrial revolution did not originate in China. Economic Development and Cultural Change 43(2), 269–292.

Loury, G. C. (1979). Market structure and innovation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 93(3), 395–410.

Lucas Jr, R. E. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics 22(1), 3–42.

Luttmer, E. G. (2011). On the mechanics of firm growth. The Review of Economic Studies 78(3), 1042–1068.

Maddison, A. (2001). The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective. Paris, France: Development Centre of the OECD Publishing.

Malanima, P. (2011). The long decline of a leading economy: GDP in central and northern Italy, 1300–1913. European Review of Economic History 15(2), 169–219.

Maloney, W. F. and F. Valencia Caicedo (2022). Engineering growth. Journal of the European Economic Association 20(4), 1554–1594.

Mathias, P. (1972). Who unbound prometheus? Science and technological change 1600–1800. In P. Mathias (Ed.), Science and Society, 1600–1900, Chapter 3, pp. 54–80. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.

McCloskey, D. (2016). Bourgeois Equality: How ideas, not capital or institutions, enriched the world. Chicago, Illinois, U.S.: University of Chicago Press.

McCusker, J. J. (2006). Colonial statistics. In S. B. Carter, S. S. Gartner, and M. R. Haines (Eds.), Historical Statistics of the United States: Earliest Time to the Present, Chapter V-671. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.

McKendrick, N. (1973). The role of science in the industrial revolution. In M. Teich and R. Young (Eds.), Changing Perspectives in the History of Science, pp. 274–319. London, U.K.: Heinemann.

Meisenzahl, R. R. and J. Mokyr (2012). The rate and direction of invention in the British industrial revolution. Chapter 9, pp. 443–482. Chicago, Illinois, U.S.: University of Chicago Press.

Melitz, M. J. (2003). The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica 71(6), 1695–1725.

Mokyr, J. (1990a). The lever of riches: Technological creativity and economic progress. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press.

Mokyr, J. (1990b). Punctuated equilibria and technological progress. The American Economic Review 80(2), 350–354.

Mokyr, J. (1992). Technological inertia in economic history. The Journal of Economic History 52(2), 325–338.

Mokyr, J. (1994). Cardwell’s law and the political economy of technological progress. Research Policy 23(5), 561–574.

Mokyr, J. (2000). The industrial revolution and the Netherlands: Why did it not happen? De Economist 148, 503–520.

Mokyr, J. (2002). The gifts of Athena: Historical origins of the knowledge economy. Princeton, New Jersey, U.S.: Princeton University Press.

Mokyr, J. (2005a). The intellectual origins of modern economic growth. The Journal of Economic History 65(2), 285–351.

Mokyr, J. (2005b). Long-term economic growth and the history of technology. In P. Aghion and S. N. Durlauf (Eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, Volume 1, Chapter 17, pp. 1113–1180. Amsterdam, The Netherlands: North-Holland.

Mokyr, J. (2009). The Enlightened economy: An economic history of Britain 1700–1850. New Haven, Connecticut, U.S.: Yale University Press.

Mokyr, J. (2016). A culture of growth: The origins of the modern economy. Princeton, New Jersey, U.S.: Princeton University Press.

Mokyr, J. (2018a). Editor’s introduction: The new economic history and the industrial revolution. In J. Mokyr (Ed.), The British industrial revolution: An economic perspective, pp. 1–84. Milton Park, U.K.: Routledge.

Mokyr, J. (2018b). The past and the future of innovation: Some lessons from economic history. Explorations in Economic History 69, 13–26.

Mokyr, J. (2020). Creative destruction or destructive creation? A prelude to the industrial revolution. In U. Akcigit and J. van Reenen (Eds.), The Economics of Creative Destruction, Chapter 26, pp. 714–735. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press.

Mokyr, J., A. Sarid, and K. Van Der Beek (2022). The wheels of change: Technology adoption, millwrights and the persistence in Britain’s industrialisation. The Economic Journal 132(645), 1894–1926.

Musson, A. E. and E. Robinson (1969). Science and technology in the industrial revolution. Manchester, U.K.: Manchester University Press.

Nadler, J. and D. N. Cicilline (2020). Investigation of competition in digital markets. Majority staff report and recommendations on antitrust, commercial, and administrative law of the committee on the judiciary of the House of Representatives (Part 1), U.S. Government Publishing Office, Washington D.C., U.S.

Nelson, R. R. and S. G. Winter (1982). The Schumpeterian tradeoff revisited. The American Economic Review 72(1), 114–132.

Nickell, S. J. (1996). Competition and corporate performance. Journal of Political Economy 104(4), 724–746.

North, D. C. (2004). Understanding the Process of Economic Change. Princeton, New Jersey, U.S.: Princeton University Press.

North, D. C. and R. P. Thomas (1973). The rise of the western world: A new economic history. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K.

North, D. C. and B. R. Weingast (1989). Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. The Journal of Economic History 49(4), 803–832.

Palma, N. and J. Reis (2019). From convergence to divergence: Portuguese economic growth, 1527–1850. The Journal of Economic History 79(2), 477–506.

Parente, S. L. and E. C. Prescott (2002). Barriers to riches. Cambridge, Massachusetts, U.S.: MIT Press.

Persson, Karl Gunnar, M. L. and P. Sharp (2025). An economic history of Europe. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.

Peters, M. (2020). Heterogeneous markups, growth, and endogenous misallocation. Econometrica 88(5), 2037–2073.

Peters, M. and C. Walsh (2021). Population growth and firm dynamics. National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 29424, Cambridge, Massachusetts, U.S.

Pomeranz, K. (2000). The great divergence: China, Europe, and the making of the modern world economy. In The Great Divergence. Princeton, New Jersey, U.S.: Princeton University Press.

Reinganum, J. F. (1985). Innovation and industry evolution. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 100(1), 81–99.

Romer, P. M. (1986). Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy 94(5), 1002–1037.

Romer, P. M. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy 98(5), 71–102.

Rosenberg, N. (1976). Perspectives on Technology. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.

Rosenberg, N. (1982). How exogenous is science? In N. Rosenberg (Ed.), Inside the Black Box: Technology and Economics, Chapter 7, pp. 141–159. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.

Sch¨on, L. and O. Krantz (2012). The Swedish economy in the early modern period: Constructing historical national accounts. European Review of Economic History 16(4), 529–549.

Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy. New York, U.S.: Harper & Brothers.

Segerstrom, P. S., T. C. Anant, and E. Dinopoulos (1990). A Schumpeterian model of the product life cycle. The American Economic Review 80(5), 1077–1091.

Solow, R. M. (1956). A contribution to the theory of economic growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 70(1), 65–94.

Solow, R. M. (1957). Technical change and the aggregate production function. The Review of Economics and Statistics 39(3), 312–320.

Squicciarini, M. P. and N. Voigtl¨ander (2015). Human capital and industrialization: Evidence from the age of enlightenment. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 130(4), 1825–1883.

Stigler Committee on Digital Platforms (2019). Final Report. Chicago, Illionois, U.S.: George J. Stigler Center for the Study of the Economy and the State.

Sutch, R. (2006). National income and product. In S. B. Carter, S. S. Gartner, and M. R. Haines (Eds.), Historical Statistics of the United States: Earliest Time to the Present, Chapter III-23-25. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.

Temin, P. (1997). Two views of the British industrial revolution. The Journal of Economic History 57 (1), 63–82.

Van Zanden, J. L. and B. Van Leeuwen (2012). Persistent but not consistent: The growth of national income in Holland 1347–1807. Explorations in Economic History 49(2), 119–130.

Voth, H.-J., B. Caprettini, and A. Trew (2023). Fighting for growth: Labor scarcity and technological progress during the British industrial revolution. CEPR Discussion Papers No. 17881.

Woodcroft, B. (1854). Alphabetical Index of Patentees of Inventions: From March 2, 1617 (14 James I.) to October 1, 1852 (16 Victoriae). London, U.K.: Queen’s Printing Office.

Xu, Y., Z. Shi, B. Van Leeuwen, Y. Ni, Z. Zhang, and Y. Ma (2017). Chinese national income, ca. 1661–1933. Ausatralian Economic History Review 57 (3), 368–393.

Zeev, N. B., J. Mokyr, and K. Van Der Beek (2017). Flexible supply of apprenticeship in the British industrial revolution. The Journal of Economic History 77 (1), 208–250.